Seth posted a very interesting and suggestive comment on my
post-safari musings about Piketty, and rather than reply in the comments
section, I would like to attempt a lengthy response. Here is what he said:
"The obstacle to socialism has never been
the theory, always the practice. How do you manage socialized capital for the
benefit of the broad citizenry without losing control of it to the leaders?
This is sometimes called the "agency problem" -- how do you ensure
(positively) the selection of trust-worthy agents and (negatively) the removal
of badly behaved agents?
Democratic socialism is the glib answer to this question, but it begs the question. How do you sustain active participation by a broad enough population when specialized knowledge and focused attention is required to manage any particular part of the socially owned enterprises?
The Polanyi brothers are a neat pair of bookends on this subject: Karl stating the social and political problem elegantly ("The Great Transformation") in its historical context, and Michael expressing the difficulty of solving it ("Personal Knowledge") given the need for specialization and reliance on others' expertise even in epistemological/scientific matters, without even getting into the sort of decision-making required of business managers.
Piketty is perhaps feeding some oxygen to the dying embers of political economy as an academic subject, but we need something more than theory. You have expressed frustration at the prospect of leaving this world before real progress can be made in these matters. I'm a good three decades younger, yet worry that my *grandchildren* will not see this resolved either."
Democratic socialism is the glib answer to this question, but it begs the question. How do you sustain active participation by a broad enough population when specialized knowledge and focused attention is required to manage any particular part of the socially owned enterprises?
The Polanyi brothers are a neat pair of bookends on this subject: Karl stating the social and political problem elegantly ("The Great Transformation") in its historical context, and Michael expressing the difficulty of solving it ("Personal Knowledge") given the need for specialization and reliance on others' expertise even in epistemological/scientific matters, without even getting into the sort of decision-making required of business managers.
Piketty is perhaps feeding some oxygen to the dying embers of political economy as an academic subject, but we need something more than theory. You have expressed frustration at the prospect of leaving this world before real progress can be made in these matters. I'm a good three decades younger, yet worry that my *grandchildren* will not see this resolved either."
First of all, Seth is of course quite
correct. Uttering the words
"Democratic Socialism" is no answer to the question, "How are
you going to make it work?" My
first thought is Oscar Wilde's wonderful quip about socialism: "It
will never work. Too many
meetings." Nor is it useful, in my
opinion, to invoke images of the Soviet Union and play them off against stories
about Scandinavia. The questions Seth
raises are actually quite complex, as we would expect, and I can only make
preliminary remarks here.
It is always useful to start this sort of
exploration with some concrete cases rather than abstract principles. Are there any examples of the American
government running large, complex bureaucratically organized operations, and if
there are, has it run them well or badly?
Well, as it happens, there are a number of
examples. Let me start with what is far
and away the largest, most complex, most
expensive, most labor intensive operation in the entire U. S. economy, public
or private: The United States Military. The official budget of the Defense Department
is seven hundred billion, give or take the odd twenty billion. The Armed Forces employ [so to speak] one and
a half million men and women, roughly two hundred thousand more than Walmart,
the biggest private employer in the country.
Now, you may not like the Armed Forces. You may not approve of the Armed Forces. But if you are clear-eyed and objective, you
will recognize that the Armed Forces of the United States is an astonishingly
efficient and well-run organization. It
trains its employees superbly and it manages them efficiently With the signal and truly awful exception of
sexual harassment, the military is the very model of a modern corporation. The U. S. military never attempts to
interfere in the political life of the country, it carries out the missions it
is assigned with great courage and effectiveness, even when those missions are
unwise in the extreme, it is almost never touched by financial scandals, and it
looks after its employees much better than most private corporations.
How is the military run? By its
senior officer corps. And what do these
men and women get paid? Well, a four
star general is paid roughly $235,000 a year, plus some perks. In other words, a general who commands enough
fire power to wipe out half a dozen medium sized countries is paid roughly as
much as a senior professor at an elite Ivy League university who is probably in
charge of a secretary and four teaching assistants. No one has ever suggested that the Army will
fall apart unless its senior managers are paid seventy million dollars a
year. Nor is there a disastrous flight
from the ranks of the officer corps to private industry.
You say you don't like anything having to do
with the military and don't even want to hear about it. O.K.
Try Medicare, Medicaid, and Social Security. The Federal Government spends 586 billion,
265 billion, and 680 billion for those three programs [in 2013]. They are run efficiently, honestly, and
without scandal. The Tennessee Valley
Authority, the National Institutes of Health, the Post Office, The Air and
Space Museum, Yellowstone National Park?
We are surrounded with efficient, honest, well-run government bureaucracies,
large and small.
Will the selection, training, and oversight of the
corps of government managers always be a problem, a task, a matter of the
greatest public important? Of
course. How could it be otherwise? Is there reason to suppose that a democratic
socialist government could do the job at least as well as is now being done by
the boards of directors of private corporations? Well, considering the disasters visited on
all of us by the captains of industry in the private sector, I think we have
reason to be optimistic about the prospects for democratic socialism.
But that is not even the most interesting
question, and one of the great values of Piketty's book is that it recalls us
to a really urgent question confronting modern economies, which, to use the
jargon of the economics trade, is the proper choice of a social rate of
savings. Let me explain.
Each year, the economy reproduces itself. Some of what is produced is consumed as
subsistence by the working class [and also as luxury consumption by the owners
of capital, but rich though they are, their annual luxury consumption is a
small share of the total output because there are not many of them, and one can
only buy so many McMansions and Lamborghinis.] A good deal more is set aside as inputs
required in the next round of production.
And some of it goes to replace worn-out capital stock -- i.e.,
depreciation. The remainder is divided
between the owners of capital in the form of profits and the workers in the
form of wages over and above whatever is considered as subsistence at that time
and in that society.
In a capitalist economy, the owners of capital are
constantly trying to drive wages down to subsistence, and the workers are doing
their best [which is often not much] to push wages above subsistence. The outcome of this push and pull determines
how much output is set aside as additional capital for future investment. In short, the struggle between capital and
labor determines the social rate of savings.
In a capitalist economy, it is extremely difficult for the
society as a whole to make collective rational choices about the desirable
social rate of savings. Should the
society consume most of what it produces and grow very slowly, or should it
tighten its collective belt and save as much as it can so as to expand future
production dramatically? In a capitalist
economy, this question cannot be raised directly, because the social rate of
savings is not directly the object of political deliberation. It is of course possible in a democratic
capitalist society for the electorate, through its representatives, to seize a
portion of the profit as taxes and distribute what has been seized as a
supplement to wages. The struggle over
such redistribution is very much the story of electoral politics in America in
the twentieth and twenty-first centuries.
In a democratic socialist society -- a society in which the
great capital accumulations are collectively owned and managed -- the question
of the desirable social rate of savings could for the first time become the
object of collective democratic deliberation.
In a sense, the question could be put quite simply: Shall we raise wages now and produce in the
future at the same level we are producing now, or shall we hold wages steady
and expand production by investing the social surplus in new plants, roads,
high speed trains, and electronic innovations?
Readers of this blog know that I have had issues, personal
and philosophical, with Jack Rawls. I
think, therefore, that I ought to take a moment to acknowledge that Rawls is,
to my knowledge, the only major social and political philosopher in the entire
history of the subject to talk about this question and recognize its important.
There is a great deal more to be said about this subject,
and I will be happy to continue if anyone is interested, but 1500 words is
enough as a response to a comment on a blog, so I will post this and go get a
cup of decaf while the world reads what I have written [I wish!]
I can't speak for the world, but I read, and look forward to the next installment
ReplyDeleteThanks for the very substantial reply. I agree that there are a lot of effective government agencies. But the guardians of the public sector are our elected officials and the voting public. And as long as the public remain confused and equate any form of public sector investment with "socialism" (which they take to mean Soviet-style dictatorship), they will be divided enough to allow the ongoing sale of public policy to the highest bidders. The US military, for example, has been rapidly shifting its logistical tasks to private sector contractors. The dismantling of the public sector has been proceeding for at least 35 or 40 years, and it is hard to see how the public mood will change sufficiently to make a difference.
ReplyDeleteThe future has a way of surprising us, so I will have to hope for something I'm not thinking of right now.
Here's a ray of hope already. The US doesn't often follow the Swiss lead on social policy, but at least this idea has the blessing of Milton Friedman and some positive press from right libertarians:
ReplyDeletehttp://www.slate.com/blogs/business_insider/2013/10/19/swiss_government_giveaway_2_800_a_month_for_all_citizens.html
"Shall we raise wages now and produce in the future at the same level we are producing now, or shall we hold wages steady and expand production by investing the social surplus in new plants, roads, high speed trains, and electronic innovations?"
ReplyDeleteI would very much like to hear your thoughts on this question.