The Hedgehog, the
Fox and Thomas Piketty
By Patrick Gideon Wolff
“The fox knows many things, but the hedgehog knows one
big thing.”
Thomas Piketty has attracted quite a lot of attention
with Capital in the Twenty-First Century.
I will try to add a few perspectives that I hope may usefully complement the book’s
huge and growing volume of thoughtful discussion.
Piketty is one of several economists (most notably also including
Emmanuel Saez) who have pioneered developing the data on the distribution of
wealth and income within economies across countries and over time. Their
scholarship is well known and impeccable. Everything has been placed
transparently and voluminously online for inspection and analysis. The data
that Capital in the Twenty-First Century draws upon is part of this enormous
mosaic, and will be critiqued, corrected and reformulated for many years to
come. From this perspective, it seems clear to me that the recent kerfuffle
raised by Chris Giles at the FT is misguided. Of course errors will be found in
Piketty’s book. But the broad facts of income and wealth inequality are well
documented and not subject to a “gotcha” fact checking exercise. Anyone who
seriously wants to advance the frontier of knowledge in this area must engage
with the broader project.
(As an aside, it is worth noting how much the Internet
has improved data scholarship by making this kind of project possible. For
example, compare Piketty’s book to another famous data-driven economics book: A Monetary History of the United States.
The data in that book were painstakingly developed by Milton Friedman and Anna
Schwartz. Imagine how much faster their data could have been checked and
interpreted if it had been possible to put it all online. How many innocent
errors in their work have never been corrected due to this lack of access? I
suspect that we greatly underestimate the base rate of academic error in such
data work, simply because it has never before been possible to analyze as
quickly and transparently as it is now. And we therefore probably fail to
appreciate how much better such data work can become in this century thanks to
computers and the internet.)
But Piketty’s book is more than just a compilation and
synthesis of the data regarding how income and wealth are now and have
historically been distributed. It is an attempt to use that data to ask a
deeply fundamental question: What failures of capitalism develop from the evolution
of the distribution of income and wealth, and what remedies suggest themselves?
The attention that Piketty’s book has attracted testifies to the poignancy of
this question at this moment in time.
Piketty had a choice between two approaches in answering
this question: he could have been a hedgehog or a fox. I submit that he chose
wrongly. He tried and failed to be a hedgehog. He would have done better to be
a fox.
The “one big thing” Piketty thinks he knows is that “r,”
the (real) private rate of return on capital is greater than “g,” the (real)
growth rate of GDP. [Henceforth, the discussion of “r” and “g” will be real
rates, i.e. net of inflation, unless otherwise indicated.] Piketty believes
that, (a) this has generally been true historically, although not true for much
of the twentieth century for idiosyncratic reasons, (b) it is highly likely to
be true again in the twenty-first century, and (c) when it is true it
inexorably drives greater and greater economic inequality unless stopped or
reversed by explicit economic policies. This idea has been critiqued from
several directions, e.g. Larry Summers (http://www.democracyjournal.org/32/the-inequality-puzzle.php?page=all)
and Jamie Galbraith (http://www.dissentmagazine.org/article/kapital-for-the-twenty-first-century).
In my opinion the general direction (and many of the specific points) of these
critiques are correct and will ultimately undermine Piketty’s “r > g” argument.
I have nothing of value to add from an economics perspective, but I would like
to make a small contribution to this critique from my perspective as a
professional money manager.
Piketty claims that the rate of return on capital has
been in the neighborhood of 4-5% in the 18th and 19th
centuries, and is likely to be close to 5% in the 21st century.
Piketty emphasizes that these are market rates of return. It therefore seems
sensible to look at today’s markets to assess the situation. I believe he significantly
overestimates the likely future returns.
Start with interest rates: the 10-year bond currently (as
of May 30, 2014) yields about 2.5%. If we assume that inflation over the next
ten years will be 1.5%, that is a real rate of return of 1% – and that’s before
taxes. (You can get a little bit more yield from the 30-year bond, 3.3%, but
the inflation risk is greater, too.) You can get a higher – although not much
higher these days! – yield with corporate bonds, but much (although hopefully
not all) of that extra yield will be lost over time to the odd default that
pops up, i.e. it is compensation for default risk.
What about real estate? Real estate is much more local,
so deriving a universal rental yield is impossible. Still, my guess is that a
house in a major metropolitan area might sell for a little less than 17 times
annual rent, for a rental yield of 6%. Since rents should generally rise
somewhat in line with inflation over time, one might initially think that this
is a real rate of return of 6% before taxes. But hold on! Unlike a bond, a
house has expenses associated with it, and those expenses could easily eat up 2-3%
of that return in order to keep its rental yield in line with inflation. And
oh, yes, there’s also risk: unlike a government bond, whose primary risk is
inflation, any real estate investment has other risks that could impair its
value over time. This is an important point, because it means that just like
the corporate bond described above, in aggregate some (but not all) of the
yield in excess to government bonds may be lost to the risk entailed.
And stocks? Well, the S&P 500 right now yields a bit
less than 2% and sells for around 17 times earnings. I agree with Warren
Buffett that stocks are in a “zone of reasonableness” right now in terms of
valuation. When stocks are reasonably valued, one should generally expect to
earn the growth in earnings per share (EPS) plus dividends over time, but no
more. Nobody knows at what rate EPS will grow but I think a reasonable guess is
5-6%, so long as corporate profit margins remain at their presently very high
level relative to history. So maybe you can expect to earn 7% before inflation
and about 5% afterwards – again, before taxes. Plus of course, there’s risk:
profits might decrease (e.g. if wages for low-skilled labor pick up), and every
so often a crisis likes 2008 forces many people to sell at precisely the wrong
time.
In other words, a quick scan of the market suggests that the
5% real rate of return that Piketty breezily assumes is – in the US, at least –
at best on offer only in the very riskiest asset class. Now you might say that
since the rich can shoulder that risk most easily they will earn the highest
possible return. Well, maybe, but be careful of the fallacy of composition:
since we are talking about the economy as a whole, we have to think about the
return of all assets, and can adjust only on the margins for how the
rich might construct their portfolios. (To put it more plainly: every asset
must be owned by someone, and the more assets that the rich own, the more what
the rich own will represent the whole.) Very roughly, if we average the
prospective future return on capital from bonds, real estate and stocks in the
US, I think you might earn a 3% real rate. That’s not shabby, but it’s not 5%
either. And it’s before taxes.
(Maybe returns will be better outside the US? Space does
not permit a detailed response to that very reasonable question, but I can
summarize my best guess: probably not. Real interest rates are very low in
virtually all rich, developed countries, and property values are much higher
relative to rents in Europe. Stocks in many developed markets do look somewhat
cheaper, but not dramatically so, and the risks abroad are also greater right
now in my opinion. And for reasons I have no space to explain here, I do not
believe that less developed countries in aggregate will offer anything like the
same returns prospectively as they have done over the last dozen years.)
Piketty is an empirically driven academic. Shouldn’t he
have addressed the current state of markets before prognosticating on the
outlook for future returns on capital? But this is the problem with the
hedgehog approach: once you are committed to the “one big thing” you think you
know (i.e. that r > g is the “principal destabilizing force” that is “potentially
threatening to democratic societies and to the values of social justice on
which they are based” [quotes from the first page of the Conclusion], all your intellectual
efforts go towards buttressing that one thing. By fixing your eyes straight
ahead, you miss everything else around you – as well as potential pitfalls that
lie underneath the intellectual path you tread.
***********************************
Now what if he had been a fox instead? In that case he
could have made many individual observations rather than try to provide a
grand, unified theory. It would have been less elegant, but possibly much more
fruitful. I cannot possibly do justice to the richness of the observations that
he could have offered, but let me very briefly outline three broad areas of
interest.
ONE: One
striking pattern from the data is that it is persistently the case that at
least 50% of the population (for any economy at any time) fails to accumulate
practically any private wealth. This is an amazing fact. It seems to me one of
the strongest arguments that could be made in favor of the modern welfare
state. It would have been fascinating to read a chapter or more by Piketty devoted
to this topic.
TWO: Middle
class wages sometimes track and sometimes undershoot their marginal
productivity – and for the last forty years, they appear to have undershot.
Piketty could potentially have made a very valuable contribution by using his
understanding of the patterns of income distribution to try to explain why and to
analyze this issue in more depth.
THREE: The
very, very top income echelons (the top 0.1% and top 0.01%) have been
dramatically pulling away from the rest of the population over the past few
decades, particularly in the US. Piketty does not overlook this topic (indeed,
he helped discover it through his data research), but as it does not fit into
his grand r > g framework his treatment in the book is superficial. I
suspect that his American readers in particular would have appreciated a much
richer analysis.
***********************************
Like many others, I found Piketty’s book to be a
fascinating and engaging read. Its popularity shows how much people care about
its topic and how well it is written. I suspect, however, that the verdict of
history will be to regard Capital in the
Twenty-First Century more as a lost opportunity than as an enduring
classic. Perhaps its greatest contribution will ultimately be to evangelize the
extraordinary, ongoing data project regarding the distribution of income and
wealth, a project of which Piketty has been one of the leaders and for which he
has deservedly earned his stellar academic reputation.
This truly one of the more insightful reviews that I have read of Piketty's work. Nicely written too.
ReplyDeletePerhaps at some point, Mr. PG Wolff could blog on the art and challenges of hedge fund managing.
Apologies for joining the discussion so late.
ReplyDeleteWhile I am satisfied with the author's argument that Piketty may have overestimated r, I have a question:
The fact that wealth inequality has increased seems indisputable. Other researchers have confirmed this and, well, it actually seems evident from just reading the news.
How does this fit with the author's critique? Maybe g was also exaggerated? Maybe current returns on investment are abnormally low?
Really nice note, coming from MR -- where Alex also showed how the Piketty assumptions about savings and depreciation replacement are so at variance with reality.
ReplyDeleteOn income at the top 0.1%, there should be more talk about restricting monopoly protection by the gov't against digital sharing ("intellectual property) for all works where at least one principal has received 100 years of median wages (about $5mil at the current median of about $51k)
Have not read Piketty, but clearly the problem does not lend itself to one big explanation, so cheers to Patrick for sussing that out
ReplyDeleteR can easily be less than G, or both negative, but, in a kleptocracy, the oligarchs/rulers will take all the oxygen.
In the end, the poor eat the rich, one way or another, and the cycle repeats.