While
I have been wrestling FranceTelecom to the mat and idly following the World
Cup, a good many more important events have crossed the threshold of my
consciousness. Some, like the bloody
struggles in the Middle East, the “honor” killings of women who married without
the approval of their male relatives, the murder of three Israeli boys, and the
revenge burning to death of a Palestinian boy, have been simply awful. Others, like the US Supreme Court ruling in
the Hobby Lobby case, have been deeply troubling. And still others, like the Republican primary
runoff in Mississippi, can best be described as curious. The purpose of this blog post is to attempt
to place them all in a conceptual framework that may help me, and my readers,
to make sense out of what has been happening.
Broadly
speaking, there are two very different traditions of democratic theory in the
modern world. The first, whose roots can
be found in the writings of a variety of French, English, and American authors,
takes as given the existence of conflicting private interests -- primarily, but
not exclusively, economic in nature –and conceives the function of
representative democracy to be the accommodation and adjustment of those
conflicts through a series of compromises arrived at by elected representatives
charged with advancing the interests of their constituents. The device of periodic elections is
deliberately designed to make the private interest of the representatives in
being re-elected depend on their success in serving the public interest by
successfully accommodating the conflicts between the interests of their
constituents and the interests of the constituents of other representatives.
The
second tradition has its roots in the great treatise of Jean-Jacques Rousseau, Of the Social Contract. Rousseau conceives of private interests as
the enemy of true democracy. In order
for a democratic state to achieve legitimacy, Rousseau argues, individuals must
set aside their private interests and each one take as his goal [or hers, although
Rousseau assumes that all the citizens are men] the general good. Only insofar as all individuals make this
fundamental adjustment do they become citizens, and only then do the decisions
they collectively agree upon become genuine laws binding on the citizenry.
According
to the first conception of democracy, the public discourse is a series of
negotiations, a never-ending effort to arrive at satisfactory compromises of
conflicting private interests. According
to the second conception, the public discourse is a debate about the correct
answer to a single question: What is the
general good?
Those,
according to the first conception, who bargain from a position of weakness or
with insufficient skill will emerge from the public sphere with unsatisfying
bargains. Those who are voted down,
according to the second conception, have failed to persuade their fellow
citizens of their vision of the general good – indeed, Rousseau actually claims
[though his supporting argument is fallacious] that those who lose the vote are
by that fact shown to have been
incorrect in their conception of the general good.
Negotiations
over conflicting interests are, by their nature, capable of adjustment, of
accommodation, of re-negotiation when the relative strengths of the negotiating
parties have altered. Half a loaf is
better than none, as the old saying has it.
Debates about the general good are inherently irresoluble save by one
party conceding that it was wrong – not that it overreached, seeking more than
could be expected, but that it was wrong.
It
is religion in the first instance and ethnic identification secondarily that
most often give rise to irresoluble disagreements about the nature of the
general good. The great promise of the
Enlightenment and its capitalist underpinnings was that society would slowly
become secularized, that religious disagreements would fade and ethnic/national
differences would evaporate, leaving a society robbed perhaps of immortal
longings [or, more precisely, of longings for immortality] but free also of the
ineradicable divisions that had engendered so many bitter and interminable
conflicts.
American
novelists have had a good deal of fun lampooning the characteristic banal
figure of the businessman – a smile of welcome on his face for all comers, a
hearty hollow laugh, a two-handed handshake for those he barely knows. My personal favorite of this familiar type
was my first father-in-law, Jim Griffin, a self-made Irish Catholic corporate
executive who worked his way up the ladder to become Vice-President for Public
Relations of Sears, Roebuck and Co.
Despite being a loyal son of the Catholic Church, a Knight of Malta for
his fund-raising and at one time President of the Catholic Boy Scouts of America,
Griffin was as malleable as a chameleon.
I will never forget him in Cambridge, MA at my wedding to his daughter,
smiling and chatting amiably with David Riesman and Barrington Moore, Jr. as
though leftie Harvard social circles were his natural habitat. There was of course a deep logic to this
inauthenticity. Your competitor one day
may be your customer the next, and you never want to alienate a potential
customer over something as irrelevant to business as religion or ethnic pride.
Many
of the violent conflicts now savaging the Middle East are disputes about what
can, in a broad sense, be described as the general good, rather than unmediated
conflicts of private interest. No doubt
there are conflicts of economic interest at stake in the war between Sunni and Shi’a
Muslims, and those are certainly amenable of negotiation, but competing
religious convictions are by their nature non-negotiable. Even when a period of religious toleration
has emerged from a long-standing religious conflict, those on both sides
continue to be deeply convinced that their opponents are damned in the eyes of
God, and when the opportunity presents itself, they rush back into battle.
Contrast
that with what appears to have happened in Mississippi in the run-off of the
Republican primary to select a candidate for the U. S. Senate. Tea Party favorite Chris McDaniel edged longtime
Republican incumbent Thad Cochran in the initial primary, neither getting the
50% + 1 needed to secure the nomination.
In the run-off, the previously rather lethargic Cochran made open appeals
to the 40% Black Mississippi vote, which has for a long time been virtually
100% Democratic. Enough Black voters,
recognizing that Cochran was indeed more likely to serve their interests than
McDaniel, voted for Cochran in the Republican primary run-off to give Cochran a
narrow victory. [The Democratic
candidate has no chance whatsoever of actually winning the seat.] This is classic interest-group politics. There is even some reason to hope that the
large Black minority may maneuver itself into the position of king-maker,
gaining thereby the power to secure some measure of responsiveness to its
interests.
Ideological
politics is exhilarating, with its commitment to inflexible principles and the
consequent in-fighting among former comrades who have strayed a hairsbreadth
from the world historical truth, and Lord knows I am by conviction and lifelong
practice more an ideological warrior than a Rotary Club glad hander, but the
events unfolding in the Middle East remind me of just what is lost when accommodation
gives way to calls for a rush to the barricades and one reaches for improvised
explosive devices.
In
my youth, I genuinely believed that the promise of the Enlightenment was being
fulfilled, and that religion and ethnic divisions were fading from the
world. Half a century farther on, I feel
as though I had stumbled into seventeenth century Europe.
1 comment:
Contact us and ask your questions and queries directly to us MCA Realtime Callback Leads Capital Brokers are receiving calls from the Qualified Merchant
Post a Comment