My Stuff

https://umass-my.sharepoint.com/:f:/g/personal/rwolff_umass_edu/EkxJV79tnlBDol82i7bXs7gBAUHadkylrmLgWbXv2nYq_A?e=UcbbW0

Coming Soon:

The following books by Robert Paul Wolff are available on Amazon.com as e-books: KANT'S THEORY OF MENTAL ACTIVITY, THE AUTONOMY OF REASON, UNDERSTANDING MARX, UNDERSTANDING RAWLS, THE POVERTY OF LIBERALISM, A LIFE IN THE ACADEMY, MONEYBAGS MUST BE SO LUCKY, AN INTRODUCTION TO THE USE OF FORMAL METHODS IN POLITICAL PHILOSOPHY.
Now Available: Volumes I, II, III, and IV of the Collected Published and Unpublished Papers.

NOW AVAILABLE ON YOUTUBE: LECTURES ON KANT'S CRITIQUE OF PURE REASON. To view the lectures, go to YouTube and search for "Robert Paul Wolff Kant." There they will be.

NOW AVAILABLE ON YOUTUBE: LECTURES ON THE THOUGHT OF KARL MARX. To view the lectures, go to YouTube and search for Robert Paul Wolff Marx."





Total Pageviews

Sunday, May 1, 2022

A LONG ANSWER TO A SHORT QUESTION

Marco Aurelio Denegri comments, “I am curious about the tools from the mathematical sciences that have been most useful to you in exploring Marx's thought. What are books that survey these applications?”

 

The simple answer would be Linear Algebra, followed by a list of titles, but there is a good deal more to be said about the subject and it might be of interest to some of you for me to elaborate.

 

Modern economic theory began in France in the 18th century with the work of a small group of scholars called Physiocrats who put forward a tabular analysis of the French agricultural economy that emphasized the fact that the inputs into any cycle of production – the seed, tools, fertilizer, and so forth – are the outputs of previous cycles of production, so that reproduction rather than production is the proper analytical concept to be employed. This important and foundational idea was taken up by Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and other classical political economists in a series of books that constituted the core of economic theory up through the beginning of the 1870s.

 

It was first Smith and then Ricardo who developed the idea that the natural price or “value” of a commodity brought to market is determined by the amount of labor directly and indirectly required for its production. Hence the phrase “labor theory of natural price” or “labor theory of value,” which captured in summary form their central analytical insight into the newly developing capitalist economy.  Although their work was powerful and sophisticated, Smith, Ricardo, and the other classical political economists used virtually no mathematics in the exposition of their theories.

 

In the 1870s, three economic theorists – Stanley Jevons, Leon Walras, and Carl Menger – more or less independently of one another introduced into economic theory the notion of marginal product, expounding their theories with the use of calculus. This so-called “triple revolution” completely transformed academic economic theory and quickly gave rise to the characteristic mathematical analyses of capitalist economies with which any student of modern economics is familiar.

 

Somewhat obscured from view by the flashy mathematics of the new economic theories was the fact that the classical economists and the new economists, the so-called neoclassicals, asked fundamentally different questions about capitalist economies and in their analyses furthermore adopted alternative and opposed simplifications for purposes of analysis. The classical political economists sought answers to three fundamental questions: first, what is the source of economic wealth (hence the full title of Adam Smith’s great work, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations)?; second, in what way is economic wealth divided among the three great classes of society, the landed gentry, the entrepreneurs, and the workers?; And third, what factors promote or place obstacles in the path of economic growth? The neoclassical economists, in contrast, sought to understand, in the famous characterization of economic theory put forward by Lionel Robbins, the efficient allocation of scarce resources with alternative uses.

 

In addition to asking different questions, the classical economists and the neoclassical economists adopted opposite simplifications to assist them in their analyses. The classical economists assumed that each commodity had only one established mode of production. From time to time, new techniques or modes of production would be introduced by entrepreneurs of an experimental turn of mind and these would either win out and become the new established mode or prove unprofitable and die away. This was of course not strictly speaking true. At any given time there were probably several established alternative modes of production for a given commodity – involving different productive techniques and different combinations of inputs – but the classical economists made the simplifying assumption that there was only one established technique for each commodity.

 

The neoclassicals made the opposite simplifying assumption. They assumed that there were in fact an infinite number of alternative ways of producing a given commodity, involving different combinations of inputs, the quantity of each one being capable of being varied by very small increments. This assumption permitted them to use the powerful mathematical tool of the calculus and so one eventually got the standard analyses of marginal product and marginal cost that fill modern economics texts and bedevil poor business students with incipient math phobia.

 

In the 1960s and 70s and 80s, a number of quite gifted mathematical economists around the world took a new look at the classical school of political economy, using modern mathematical techniques to analyze and test the truth of the propositions advanced by Ricardo, Marx and the others. They found that the appropriate tool for translating the theories of the classicals into rigorous mathematical form is not calculus but rather linear algebra. The reason, quite simply, is that if each commodity has a single mode of production, then an entire economy can be represented by a system of linear equations, each of which relates quantities of inputs of a given commodity to the quantity of its output.

 

This formal reconsideration of the classical school began with the work of the great Italian–English economist Piero Sraffa, who not insignificantly was the general editor of the magnificent 10 volume edition of the works of David Ricardo.  Sraffa himself in his seminal monograph Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, published in 1960, did not in fact make use of linear algebra but the economists inspired by his work did.

 

Michio Morishima in Japan, Luigi Pasinetti and Pierangelo Garegnani in Italy, Gilbert Abraham-Frois and Edward Berrebi in France, and Andras Brody in Hungary, among others recast the central ideas of Ricardo and Marx in mathematical form and demonstrated that many of the most important claims that they had advanced in their works could in fact be given rigorous mathematical demonstrations.

 

That, as briefly and simply as I can state it, is the answer to Marco Aurelio Denegri’s question.

20 comments:

Anonymous said...

Cf. https://rwer.wordpress.com/2022/04/28/on-mathematics-and-economics/

DJL said...

Sraffa an Italian-English economist? Nonsense, he was Italian through and through, born to Italian parents, and grew up in Italy; he moved to England permanently as an adult because of fascism (you know, the actual one), hardly spoke English at first, and he never applied to become a British citizen (there's no English citizenship, of course) - in fact, he was interred in England during the Second World War as an enemy alien, and just in these terms, it's a disgrace to call him English.

Marco Aurelio Denegri said...

Thank you very much for the reply professor. It was very useful to look at the historical context.

Achim Kriechel (AK) said...

@ DJL
A friendly note would have been quite enough!

Sonic said...

I heard an economist describe the field as unique because of the way the different schools of study don't tend to reference each other very much. As I understand it, he was complaining that the neo-keynesian school doesn't usually study Friedman very much and the Austrian economists never respond to works published by neo-classical theorists, or something like that. Compared to other academic fields, there's not much cross-pollination.

I kind of understand why that might be now. There's so much of it! You could spend a whole life reading just one school of economic texts.

DJL said...

@AK

It WAS a friendly note

David Zimmerman said...

To DJL:

Elementary note about courtesy and rhetoric:

To characterize another person's message as "a disgrace" is not friendly.

Robert Paul Wolff said...

Piero Sraffa moved to Cambridge University when he was 27 years old and lived in England until he died at the age of 85.

Achim Kriechel (A.K.) said...

I wonder:
Apart from economic theory and its mathematical foundations, what about Marx's concepts of "labor," "alienation," or the "fetish character of commodities" today? Given the business models of Google, Facebook, Twitter, Amazon, etc. (just to name the usual suspects).

Apart from the vanishingly small number of people who actually "physically" work for these companies, these companies generate their capital from the "labor" of their customers. When I'm done with this commentary and hit the "send" button, Google's cash register rings. And I wonder how much capital Prof. Wollf's blog and his Youtube videos have generated for Google. And all this happens without payment. Even the possibility to "feel unhappy", to "mortify your mind" and to feel "unfree and forced" is eliminated as a possible perception from the process.

Anonymous said...

Sraffa lived in England from the age of 27 to the age of 85? So what? That doesn’t make him English at all, and he would have never been regarded as English by anyone in England. Typical of Americans to apply their own concepts to other countries and peoples. And in any case no-one refers to him as English on the net, only as Italian.

Eric said...

Who leaked?
https://www.politico.com/news/2022/05/02/supreme-court-abortion-draft-opinion-00029473

LFC said...

If the leak is genuine (I heard this on the radio news, haven't read the Politico article), it has to come from inside the Court, which narrows down the field: there are only nine chambers. That said, the precise source of the leak may never be known. Probably a person or persons unhappy with Alito's draft.

LFC said...

P.s. V possibly one of the law clerks.

aaall said...

Given what a leak might do to a clerk's career, the ridiculous nature of Alito's draft, and the stakes, I wouldn't put it past one of four.

How we got here (in part):

“The politics of fear has delivered everything we were afraid of. It's important to take a lesson from the days of Richard Nixon, when people stood up under a very oppressive president with a very oppressive Supreme Court. We got the Supreme Court, we pressured the Supreme Court into supporting women's rights to choose.” Jill Stein, Green Party presidential candidate 2016.

LFC said...

aaall
Since you think there's only a one in four chance that a clerk leaked it, who do you think leaked it?

LFC said...

Or by "one of four" do you mean one of four Justices? That strikes me as even more unlikely.

LFC said...

P.s. A leak is not going to do anything to a law clerk's career unless it's traced to him or her reasonably quickly (meaning not ten years from now), and the chances of that seem low.

Robert Vienneau said...

Sraffa and linear algebra show is that the marginal revolution (Jevons, Menger, Walras) were mistaken. This may have something to do with why mainstream economists ignore those who build on Sraffa. Marx's distinction between vulgar and scientific political economy has something to recommend it.

Some others who applied linear algebra in interesting ways to economics include Leontief, von Neumann, and (most obscurely) Maurice Potron.

DJL said...

@ Zimmerman

You sure are obsessed with minutiae, aren't you?

Another 'elementary note about courtesy and rhetoric', though: don't butt in where no-one has invited you to.

LFC said...

@ R Vienneau
Speaking of "vulgar" vs scientific, Marx said in Critique of the Gotha Program that vulgar socialism had borrowed from the bourgeois economists the (incorrect) notion that distribution is independent of the mode of production. Then in the early and mid 20th cent, capitalist welfare states effected some redistribution, showing that, *at least to a limited extent*, distribution is indeed independent of the mode of production.