While I think through my replies to several very interesting and important questions posed by readers in response to my invitation to ask me anything, I will just pass along a little calculation I made a few moments ago with the aid of a Consumer Price Index Calculator I found on-line.
I started at Harvard as a Freshman in 1950. I remember the tuition as $400 that year, but my classmate, friend, colleague, and one-time apartment mate Charles Parsons recalls it as $600, and in matters of this sort, I learned six decades ago, Charles is always right. The CPI Calculator tells me that $600 in 1950 is the equivalent of a tad less than $6,000 today -- a ten-fold devaluation. But Harvard's tuition this year is roughly $45,000, which is seven and a half times as much as a mere cost-of-living adjustment would explain.
Is Harvard's education today seven and a half times better than the education I received? I can assure you the answer is "No."
Indeed, is it as good? I will pass on that question, but I am quite certain it is no better.
Why does Harvard charge an extra $39,000 in 2015-16? There really is only one possible answer: Because it can. It gives one pause.
A Commentary on the Passing Scene by Robert Paul Wolff rwolff@afroam.umass.edu
Thursday, December 31, 2015
Wednesday, December 30, 2015
YET MORE RESPONSES TO QUESTIONS
Ask, and it shall be given
you; seek, and ye shall find -- Matthew,
7:7
Bereft of inspiration,
afloat in a dead zone of the Ocean of Blog, I invited questions, and lo, they
have come.
Andrew Blais [who, under my
direction but without much assistance from me, wrote a fine doctoral
dissertation later published as a book], asks whether my choice of comrades has
been general or personal. Early in my
life, it was general: I picketed Woolworth's in Cambridge at a time when I
think I did not know a single African-American; early on, I declared myself on
the side of the workers, but without having ever held a real working job save
as a summer Copy Boy at the New York Herald
Tribune [a plum secured through the influence of my mother, who had a
generation earlier worked as the secretary to the Trib's city editor.] Later
on, however, my commitments were mediated by personal connections. Quite the most intense and long-lasting of
those commitments was to the anti-apartheid cause and the transformation of the
new South Africa, a quarter-century long involvement that grew out of the personal
and intensely political friendships I formed during my initial visits to South
Africa in 1986 and 87. Indeed, my
participation in the 1986 Harvard protest arose out of a dinner with a former
student who invited me to come along.
Steven J. asks: "Do you have any
observations on the evolution of education system-at all or any levels? Ideas from Ideal of the University became
topics discussed with fellow-students and administrators at the time."
There have been at least eight major
transformations of American higher education during the sixty-six years that I
have been involved with that sector of society as student or professor. Let me sketch them briefly before I offer
some observations. The first
transformation has been an explosion in the size of the higher educational
sector. When I went off to college in
1950, roughly 5% of Americans twenty-five or older held undergraduate college
degrees. Today, somewhat more than35%
do. That is, all by itself, an enormous
change. It has created a society deeply
divided along the line of educational credentials, with the majority
[two-thirds] on the outside looking in.
The second major transformation, intimately connected
with the first, has been the growth of the public higher educational
sector. Before World War II, and up until
the '60s, private higher education dominated, but the multiplication of state
university satellite campuses and state college systems [along with the creation
of the Community College world] has radically changed both the financing and
the character of higher education. Some
of the state systems, such as the one in California, are larger than the entire
higher educational systems of major industrial nations. A side-effect of this explosion, by the way,
has been the nationalization of colleges and universities that were previously
regional in character. Some of the Ivy
League universities and other elite institutions, which before the war were
really regional in character, have actively
sought a national student body.
The third major transformation, a side-effect of
the first two, has been the complete change in the admissions process. Before the war, colleges had what could best
be described as admissions requirements. An applicant who met the requirements was
pretty well assured of admission. Even
in 1949-50, when I applied to Harvard, only about 2200 young men applied, and
of those roughly 1650 were admitted.
Twelve hundred fifty of us showed up to enroll the next September. It was much easier to get into Harvard then than
it is to get into UMass now. [I actually
did not want to go to Harvard because they required that one wear a tie and
jacket to every meal, even breakfast, but Swarthmore, my other choice, turned
me down on the grounds that I was receiving psychotherapy, so I had to go to
Harvard.] Sometime in the late '50s, the
picture changed, with applications to desired schools [I avoid the judgmental
"desirable"] so far outpacing available slots that an admissions policy was required. I have written about the baleful effects of
this change in a chapter of The Ideal of the University called
"The Admissions Rat Race."
The fourth major transformation, starting in the
'60s as a consequence of the Civil Rights Movement, was the admission of
something more than token numbers of African-Americans, and the consequent
creation, in response to their protests, of sizeable numbers of programs,
committees, and actual departments of Afro-American Studies [see the discussion
in my book, Autobiography of an Ex-White
Man.]
The fifth major transformation, now unhappily
being undone, was the establishment of faculty tenure as a norm throughout the
higher educational sector. Most academics
these days do not realize that tenure has been, by and large, a post-war
phenomenon. Indeed, by a stroke of good
luck that I quite naturally interpreted as evidence of my genius, I managed to
live out my half century long career during the golden age of faculty employment,
with tenure, sabbaticals, and two-course per semester teaching loads
commonplace on major university campuses and elsewhere. [If you think that is the historical norm,
ask Immanuel Kant, who lectured as much as seventeen hours a week as a privatdozent at the University of Königsberg
and was paid per student enrolled before his elevation to the Professorship of
Logic and Metaphysics in 1770.]
The sixth major transformation, fueled both by
the growth in higher education and by the Selective Service laws during the
Viet Nam war, was a change in the motivation and character of the professoriate,
which saw countless young men discover a calling as university professors, the
preparation for which took them safely past the age at which they were eligible
for the draft. [I made the mistake of
earning my doctorate at twenty-three, and so had to serve six months on active
duty and five and a half years in the National Guard.]
A seventh major transformation was the inclusion
of more than token numbers of women in the professoriate, with the well-known
shock delivered by the change to the curriculum, campus culture, and norms of
the Academy. At Harvard in the '50s and
'60s, brilliant young men were encouraged to go on to graduate study. Equally or more brilliant Radcliffe students
were expected to marry they Section Leaders and keep house for them. The small but important world of elite
women's colleges [the so-called Seven Sisters and their like] kept alive the deviant
idea that women had brains.
And the eighth major transformation was the
explosive growth in the cost of higher education, has which tens of millions of
college students to burden themselves with loans that will take half a lifetime
to pay off. As we old Marxists like to
say, it is no accident that the loan
burden, which prohibits college graduates from pursuing low-paying politically
rebellious career paths, came into being at just about the time when opposition
to the Viet Nam War was threatening to breed up a generation of radicals.
As you might expect, I have welcomed some of
these transformations and condemned others.
Educationally speaking, is this a better world than the one I entered in
1950? I would say it is, if only because
it is much more open and inclusive. Are
the trends positive? Very definitely
no. I am quite convinced that in a
generation, people in the Academy will look back at the second half of the
twentieth century as the Golden Age of American higher education.
THE REPUBLICAN PRESIDENTIAL CAMPAIGN -- SHH
The story has it that once, during a battle, one of Napoleon's marshals came up to him and reported that the enemy was making a flanking maneuvre, which was clearly tactically unwise. "What shall we do?" the marshal asked. Napoleon is said to have replied [the provenance on this one is a trifle clouded], "Never interrupt your enemy when he is making a mistake."
I offer this as an explanation for my silence concerning the circular firing squad of Bush, Rubio, Christie, and Kasich that has commenced fire in New Hampshire.
I offer this as an explanation for my silence concerning the circular firing squad of Bush, Rubio, Christie, and Kasich that has commenced fire in New Hampshire.
A REPLY TO PAUL
In response to my cri de coeur, Paul asks a complex and interesting question, which I
shall try to address. Here is what he
has to say:
"On several occasions you've mentioned that
long work has led you to conclude that there is no neutral pou sto from which,
by rational deliberation alone, we can decide the appropriate principles of
distributive justice on which to base a social order. As a consequence, you
maintain that the most fundamental decision each of us makes in life is our
choice of comrades. My own theory of justice is a not very coherent kitchen
table blend of Rawls, Lomasky and some luck egalitarianism. As I approach
retirement I sometimes think that I should spend some time sharpening it up but
suspect that my untutored efforts would not leave me with any great
satisfaction. I'm interested in your reflections on choice of comrades. Can
this sort of choice be usefully placed on a spectrum which might have a
Kierkegaardian choice on one end and a Benthamite calculus on the other - or
does that sort of characterization of the choice miss something important? Do
you think that ultimately incomplete or unsatisfying theories of justice are
important guides to or constraints on the choice?"
Each of us is born into an historical, social,
economic, and cultural moment that shapes who we are and how we experience the
world long before we are old enough to reflect on such things thoughtfully. As Erik Erikson writes, in a passage I am
fond of quoting, "An individual life is the accidental coincidence of but
one life cycle with but one segment of history." [Childhood
and Society.] Had I been an eleventh
century Frankish serf or a first century B. C. Roman senator or a Mayan priest
or a Mongol horseman, or indeed a nineteenth century British MP, not only would
my beliefs be quite different, so even would be the psychodynamic organization
of my personality.
But though I am aware of the extent to which I am embedded
in my "one life cycle," I am also aware that I have choices that will
shape my moral and political commitments.
I can choose to identify with the interests of my social and economic
class, which in my case is the White educated upper middle class of late
twentieth and early twenty-first century America, or I can choose to make common
cause with working class American men and women of many races. Since the interests of these two groups of
people are in important ways opposed, this choice of comrades, as I have called
it, has implications for my politics.
There are times when the choices I have made place me in
stark and immediate confrontation with those who have made different choices,
as when I sat down in front of Memorial Hall in Cambridge, Mass. in an
anti-apartheid demonstration and blocked some of my classmates from attending a
fund-raising dinner during Harvard's 350th anniversary celebrations, or when I
stood with students and faculty on the campus of the University of the
Witwatersrand in Johannesburg confronting police who had come to the campus to
disperse us.
I do not experience the choices I have made as guided by, or
indeed even inspired by, philosophical texts I have read. I experience these as choices of people with
whom I make common cause, not as choices of doctrines with which I have some sympathy. If I were to ask what has influenced my
decision to be, as we say, a man of the left , I would be more likely to cite
the inspiration of my grandfather, Barnet Wolff, who devoted his life to the
Socialist Party of New York City, and [in a negative way] the example of his
son, my father, who fell away from the socialism of his youth to become a loyal
supporter of the Democratic Party of FDR.
As I have written, when I finally conceded defeat in my long
effort to find in the philosophy of Immanuel Kant a persuasive argument for the
universal validity of a fundamental moral principle on which to ground my
actions, I experienced that failure as a liberation. Odd as it may seem, I felt free to choose my
comrades, to take sides, and to act, confident that although there could be
many arguments calling into question the particular ways in which I implemented
my commitments, there could be no argument demonstrating that I had chosen the
wrong side. That choice was a life
choice, a decision as to whom I chose to be.
Kant, Kierkegaard, Bentham, Kant, even Marx could not in effect make
that choice for me.
As I look back on a long life, now eighty-two years in the
unfolding, I am conscious of many, many ways in which I have fallen short, but I
have no doubts at all about the choice of comrades I made early in my
life. There shall be no chapter by me in
an updated edition of The God That Failed.
Tuesday, December 29, 2015
NO EXIT
I have read that there are large dead zones in the world's
oceans -- places where accumulations of plastic and other inert garbage have
virtually killed off life, so that pretty much nothing grows there, from
microorganisms to large schools of fish.
That is how I have always experienced the week between Christmas and New
Year 's Day -- a spiritual, intellectual, cultural dead zone. When I was young, this time was filled by the
Eastern Division meetings of the American Philosophical Association, but I am
afraid those meetings have taken on something of the character of dead zones
too.
What to do? I have
binge watched the first season of Mozart
in the Jungle on my Amazon Prime, but the second season is not available
until tomorrow. I have completed my
preparations for the first lecture in the Ideological
Critique series, but I want to wear a sweater on camera, so I am waiting
until it gets cold enough to start filming.
I have analyzed Donald Trump's chances of winning the Republican
nomination in more detail than any sane person could possibly desire. If I had enough socks, I would arrange my
sock drawer.
Is there anyone out there with an unanswered question? Like Gorgias in the Dialogue of the same
name, I am in itinerant wise man who claims to be able to talk on any subject
the audience may demand.
Sunday, December 27, 2015
DOUBLE PRIME
Forty-one times two equals eighty-two, my age today. Now begins the twenty-one day period when Susie and I are the same age. It has been this way since we were teenagers [needless to say.] We shall celebrate, appropriately enough, by seeing the new Michael Caine movie "Youth," after which we shall have Chinese food, a New York Jewish holiday tradition.
Saturday, December 26, 2015
A HARD ACT TO FOLLOW
December 26th, the day each year that falls between Jesus' birthday and mine.
"Hegel remarks somewhere that all great world-historic facts and personages appear, so to speak, twice. He forgot to add: the first time as tragedy, the second time as farce." Karl Marx, The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Napoleon.
"Hegel remarks somewhere that all great world-historic facts and personages appear, so to speak, twice. He forgot to add: the first time as tragedy, the second time as farce." Karl Marx, The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Napoleon.
Friday, December 25, 2015
AVANTI
Well, as Donald Rumsfeld observed, you go to war with the army you have, not the army you want. Wise advice. After the New Year, I shall deliver my lectures with the voice I have, not the voice I want. I shall begin, as Rumsfeld did not, with a little shlock and aw shucks, after which, full speed ahead.
Wednesday, December 23, 2015
STOP THE PRESSES
I have been having some sort of odd voice problems that make me more or less permanently hoarse. After a course of an anti-fungal medication that does not seem to have corrected the problem, I am due to start voice therapy [not to be confused with psychoanalysis!] on January 8th.
It is possible that I shall have to postpone the recording of my lectures for a bit. I hope not, but we shall see. My plan had been to start the weekly lectures more or less when UNC starts its Spring semester, which is to say early in January.
It is possible that I shall have to postpone the recording of my lectures for a bit. I hope not, but we shall see. My plan had been to start the weekly lectures more or less when UNC starts its Spring semester, which is to say early in January.
MUSINGS ON THE EVE OF CHRISTMAS EVE
Well, Brian Leiter's link to my old essay about Macros and
PCs produced a flood of visits to this blog -- 2500+ in a day, rather than the
usual 1000 -- and several lengthy comments.
[D. Ghirlandaio, who appears to have adopted, as a handle, the name of a
famous Renaissance Italian painter, is pretty clearly angry with me, though I
confess I do not quite understand why.]
But reflecting on the essay and the responses got me thinking about
something that has long interested me, so I thought I would follow up with a
few extended remarks about the difference between identity politics [as it is
sometimes called] and old-fashioned radical politics.
Marx observed correctly that capitalism is the most
revolutionary force ever loosed upon the world.
It destroyed feudalism, transformed the law, politics, and even the
religion of the old order, eliminated the age-old division between the city and
the countryside, ate away at the most intimate relations of the family, and, of
course, produced an explosion of production and innovation. Marx may have been overly optimistic that
capitalism would substitute the cash nexus for ethnic, religious, national, and
other divisions among men and women, thereby preparing the way for a naked
clash between labor and capital, but he was not wrong about capitalism's
tendency in this direction.
To the capitalist, unencumbered by traditional loyalties and
identifications, all that matters is keeping production costs low and finding a
market for output. To the true capitalist,
national borders are merely impediments to trade; the family wage is an irrational and
unacceptable obstacle to lowering the price of labor; racial or sexual
obstacles in the labor market drive up wages; and any social constraints on the
largest possible pool of job-seeking workers is to be resisted as a restraint
on profits.
The true capitalist cannot afford to turn up his nose at a
customer or an investor of a different nationality, religion, ethnicity, or
race, because a competitor of a less delicate sensibility will step in and take
away his business.
To be sure, although this is the inner logic of capitalism,
the reality often can be quite other.
For example, in the later nineteenth century, some white northern
workers made a devil's bargain with their employers, accepting lower wages in
return for the exclusion of the newly freed ex-slaves from good industrial
jobs.
The real threat to capitalism has always been not women or
Blacks or Jews or Catholics or foreigners in the labor market, but organized
workers using their collective power to compel higher wages, better working
conditions, and shorter hours, all of which threatened profits. Thus it was that capitalists, calling on the
organized military might of the state, did everything in their power to crush
unions, often in bloody pitched battles.
And more recently, when affirmative action at America's universities has
been challenged in the courts, multi-national corporations have filed amicus briefs defending such programs,
quite correctly judging that any program that increases the availability of
well-trained workers of all races and ethnicities will help to drive down
wages.
For more than a century now, America has seen a series of
Liberation movements -- Women's Liberation, the Civil Rights Movement, LGBT
Liberation -- all of which, fundamentally, express the demand that a portion of
the population excluded from full and fair participation in the labor market,
be freed from the restrictions denying them jobs and wages as well as the
education they need to compete successfully for those jobs.
These movements, although they use the language and evoke
the emotions of revolutionary change, are in reality demands not for the
overthrow of capitalism but for its perfection.
It is contrary to the inner logic of capitalism to exclude the female
half of the population from the workplace, because the smaller the pool of
workers, the stronger the upward pressure on wages. From the point of the view of the industrialist,
the so-called "family wage" -- a salary for industrial workers
sufficient to support a wife and children -- is an irrational expense deducted
from profits. Far better a multi-worker
household making essentially the same total wage but offering in return many
more hours of labor.
For someone my age and of my ideological leanings, it has been
fascinating to watch the ease with which the corporate world has co-opted the symbols of
protest and reduced them to advertising images and gimmicks. Time was when you could tell the politics of
a young man at fifty paces by the length of his hair, when artificially amped
up music devoid of aesthetic merit was the sound of protest against "the
system," when body piercings were a dagger in the heart of The
Establishment. All of this was
brilliantly anatomized by my old friend, Herbert Marcuse, under the provocative
heading "repressive desublimation."
Despite its ephemeral nature and lack of an agenda for
action, the most serious thrust at the established order in recent years has been
the Occupy Movement. Income and wealth
inequality is a consequence of capitalism, not a cause, but it is the right
target for the early stages of a serious movement for fundamental change. Yesterday, a protest against Wall Street. Today a self-proclaimed Democratic Socialist
as a respectable challenger to the inevitable Democratic presidential
nominee. Tomorrow, dare I hope for a
modern revival and transformation of the union movement, that, in the words of
the bumper sticker, gave us the weekend?
Tuesday, December 22, 2015
REVISED DELEGATE ESTIMATE
Prodded by my son, Patrick, I completely re-did the state by state estimate of the delegates Trump would win if certain assumptions held true. He then converted it all into a spreadsheet. Here, first, are my assumptions and abbreviations:
I. General Explanation
With all that said, here is the spreadsheet information:
I. General Explanation
These estimates are keyed to the Green Papers, a detailed
specification of the rules governing the several state primaries. I omit caucuses, which take place in fifteen of
the states and territories, because I do not understand the rules governing
them well enough to make any estimates.
The numbers in the Green Papers have changed since I began
this effort. Originally, they stated
that 2484 delegates would be sent to the Convention in July. Now they say there will be 2472. I have no idea what happened to the other twelve. As of now, it will require 1237 votes at the
Convention to choose a nominee. The
Green Papers still list 1865 as the delegates to be chosen by primaries and
caucuses, which leaves 607 so-called "super-delegates."
What is more, the rules in some states have
changed since I last read them!
Sheeesh!!! Therefore, this
exercise will yield different results.
II. Assumptions
This
exercise is not intended to produce
a prediction of the outcome. It is a calculation of the likely result
given certain assumptions. Here are the
assumptions on which the calculation is based:
(a) Fairly quickly,
the race reduces to a three way contest among Trump, Cruz, and Rubio, with several
other candidates remaining in the race but garnering, among them, no more than
20% of the total vote.
(b) Trump gets a
steady 35-40% of the vote.
(c) Cruz and Rubio
between them get 40-50% of the vote, with neither getting as high as 30% save
in one or two states.
(d) Few if any of the
super-delegates will vote for Trump at the Convention, so if he is to get the
nomination, he must win the 1237 delegates in the primaries and caucuses, which
is to say 66.4% of them.
III. Important facts
(a) The Republican
National Committee allocates 3 delegates to a state for each Congressional
District [CD], plus some number of delegates-at-large.
(b) The elected
delegates are pledged to a candidate and must vote for him or her on the first ballot
at the Convention. The super-delegates
are unpledged [at least in some cases!!!
But see South Carolina.] and may
vote for anyone [I think this is true, but the Green Papers are unclear.]
IV. Abbreviations
(a) WTA =
Winner takes all. The highest
vote getter wins all of the delegates selected in a primary.
(b) WTM =
Winner takes most. A delegate
allocation system that gives some delegates to the second and even third place
finishers in a primary but allocates an out-sized proportion to the candidate
getting the most votes. For example, in
each CD, a state may award 2 of the delegates to the top vote getter in that CD
and 1 to the second-place vote getter.
The at-large delegates may be allocated proportionally to the vote getters
in the state who get 20% or more of the total vote. [This is quite common. Note that if Trump gets 40%, Cruz gets 25%,
and Rubio gets 20%, then Trump gets 47% of the at-large delegates, because 40%
is 47% of 85%.]
(c) PROP =
genuine proportional allocation of delegates according to the popular
vote. Very few states use this system,
but New Hampshire, the first primary, does.
With all that said, here is the spreadsheet information:
State | Pledged Delegates | Likely Trump | % of Total | System |
New Hampshire | 20 | 7 | 35.0% | PROP |
South Carolina | 50 | 41 | 82.0% | WTM |
Alabama | 47 | 32 | 68.1% | WTM |
Arkansas | 37 | 14 | 37.8% | PROP |
Georgia | 76 | 40 | 52.6% | WTM |
Massachusetts | 39 | 14 | 35.9% | PROP |
Okalahoma | 40 | 20 | 50.0% | WTM |
Tennessee | 55 | 28 | 50.9% | WTM |
Texas | 152 | 86 | 56.6% | WTM |
Vermont | 16 | 6 | 37.5% | PROP |
Virginia | 46 | 17 | 37.0% | PROP |
Louisiana | 44 | 16 | 36.4% | PROP |
Idaho | 29 | 10 | 34.5% | PROP |
Mississippi | 37 | 14 | 37.8% | PROP |
Michigan | 56 | 21 | 37.5% | PROP |
Puero Rico | 20 | 7 | 35.0% | PROP |
Ohio | 63 | 63 | 100.0% | WTA |
Florida | 99 | 99 | 100.0% | WTA |
Illinois | 66 | 25 | 37.9% | |
Missouri | 49 | 34 | 69.4% | WTM |
North Carolina | 72 | 25 | 34.7% | PROP |
Arizona | 58 | 58 | 100.0% | WTA |
Wisconsin | 42 | 30 | 71.4% | WTM |
New York | 92 | 52 | 56.5% | WTM |
Connecticut | 25 | 14 | 56.0% | WTM |
Delaware | 16 | 16 | 100.0% | WTA |
Maryland | 38 | 29 | 76.3% | WTM |
Pennsylvania | 68 | 14 | 20.6% | |
Rhode Island | 16 | 6 | 37.5% | PROP |
Indiana | 54 | 45 | 83.3% | WTM |
West Virginia | 31 | 18 | 58.1% | |
Oregon | 25 | 9 | 36.0% | PROP |
California | 169 | 145 | 85.8% | WTM |
Montana | 24 | 24 | 100.0% | WTA |
New Jersey | 48 | 48 | 100.0% | WTA |
New Mexico | 21 | 8 | 38.1% | PROP |
South Dakota | 26 | 26 | 100.0% | WTA |
Nebraska | 33 | 33 | 100.0% | WTA |
Washington | 41 | 14 | 34.1% | PROP |
1940 | 1208 | 62.3% |
Monday, December 21, 2015
IMPROVEMENTS
My son, Patrick, who is way better at this sort of thing than I am, took my table and put it into an Excel spreadsheet, cleaning things up along the way. Here is the result, which is clearer and more detailed than what I posted. The numbers are still somewhat screwed up, because of errors I made along the way, but I think the basic message remains: Given the assumptions with which I began, Trump could win the nomination by the end of the primary/caucus process.
State | Total | Likely Trump | % of Total |
New Hampshire | 20 | 7 | 35.0% |
South Carolina | 45 | 36 | 80.0% |
Alabama | 47 | 25 | 53.2% |
Arkansas | 37 | 18 | 48.6% |
Georgia | 76 | 39 | 51.3% |
Massachusetts | 39 | 15 | 38.5% |
Okalahoma | 40 | 21 | 52.5% |
Tennessee | 55 | 28 | 50.9% |
Texas | 155 | 72 | 46.5% |
Vermont | 16 | 8 | 50.0% |
Virginia | 46 | 16 | 34.8% |
Louisiana | 43 | 21 | 48.8% |
Idaho | 32 | 16 | 50.0% |
Mississippi | 37 | 16 | 43.2% |
Michigan | 56 | 21 | 37.5% |
Puero Rico | 20 | 10 | 50.0% |
Ohio | 63 | 63 | 100.0% |
Florida | 99 | 99 | 100.0% |
Illinois | 66 | 40 | 60.6% |
Missouri | 52 | 39 | 75.0% |
North Carolina | 69 | 23 | 33.3% |
Arizona | 58 | 58 | 100.0% |
Wisconsin | 42 | 36 | 85.7% |
New York | 95 | 47 | 49.5% |
Connecticut | 25 | 17 | 68.0% |
Delaware | 16 | 16 | 100.0% |
Maryland | 38 | 29 | 76.3% |
Pennsylvania | 54 | 18 | 33.3% |
Rhode Island | 16 | 7 | 43.8% |
Indiana | 54 | 48 | 88.9% |
West Virginia | 31 | 18 | 58.1% |
Kentucky | 46 | 16 | 34.8% |
Oregon | 25 | 9 | 36.0% |
California | 169 | 130 | 76.9% |
New Jersey | 51 | 51 | 100.0% |
New Mexico | 21 | 10 | 47.6% |
South Dakota | 26 | 26 | 100.0% |
District of Columbia | 19 | 10 | 52.6% |
1899 | 1179 | 62.1% | |