Faithful readers of this blog will have noticed that I do
not actually read very much, for all that I strive to lard my posts with arcane
references, but at the moment, I am actually reading three books, one suggested
by my sister, Barbara, one suggested by my son, Patrick, and one suggested [at
my request] by my son, Tobias. Barbara recommended
Frans de Waals’ Mama’s Last Hug, a book,
as the subtitle says, about “animal emotions and what they tell us about ourselves.” Patrick recommended Modern Monetary Theory, by L. Randall Wray. Tobias recommended the late Eve Kosofsky
Sedgwick’s Epistemology of the Closet. I am a very slow reader, so I am only 25
pages into the de Waal, 102 pages into the Wray, and I have barely completed
the Preface to the Sedgwick. I will let
you know how they turn out.
Sunday, April 28, 2019
Saturday, April 27, 2019
THE PEACE THAT PASSETH ALL UNDERSTANDING
All my life I have been writing, talking, marching, donating
for politics, but the truth is that I do not really enjoy it. I am not a happy warrior, and these days, I
am in a more or less constant state of agitation, anger, outrage, frustration,
and disappointment. All of this was
brought home to me unexpectedly a day or so ago when I was driving home with
Susie after running a series of errands.
I turned on the car radio, which is tuned to a local classical music station,
just as the announcer introduced an early baroque concerto for lute and
flute. Quite unbidden, a feeling of
peace descended on me as the music began, and for a few precious moments the agita that is my constant companion
evaporated.
Afterward, I reflected that during my entire life, there
have been two things, and only two, that can bless me with genuine inner peace. The first is early music. The second is laying out, in my mind, a
complex, powerful, beautiful idea that I have managed to master until I can
explain it so simply that my imaginary audience can see its power and
beauty. Often when I am walking in the
morning I will imagine myself addressing a group of students or a university
audience about Kant, or Marx, or Game Theory, setting forth an argument
transparently and quietly. I feel at
peace.
I remember once seeing YoYo Ma at Tanglewood, playing a Bach
Suite for unaccompanied cello. His eyes
were shut, and he was leaning back away from the instrument as though he was
not so much playing it as listening to it, having long since mastered the
technique of playing and settled on an interpretation of that immortal music. I do not think I was wrong to think that he
was at peace.
SORRY ABOUT THAT. HERE IT IS.
Great piece on the problem of Joe Biden, but there is another big problem—really big.I grew up and live in Iowa and have been to every caucus since 1980—I’ve chaired every caucus in my present precinct for over 20 years. The thing about Iowa, for obvious reasons, is that you can get really involved in presidentials and through those years, there have been a handful of them that I have thrown myself into in addition to the local stuff. One of those years was 1988, for Joe Biden. I respected him and, still single no kids, young professional living in downtown Des Moines—walking distance from his campaign headquarters, I threw myself into the race.
Everything you wrote is accurate, but there is one other aspect to Biden: he is a lousy presidential campaigner. Lousy. A lot of Democrats are rightfully worried about Bernie in a general election, but they should be also be worried about Joe—Trump will kill him. It’s more than the speaking before thinking, though that is a part of the problem. It is also in his indecision, his inability to focus on a strategy, his call with Anita Hill, all which have been on display already in this race. He is just not good at this. Great guy; great senator; great VP—and he would make a great president, too. But he cannot run a decent race for president. Maybe it is the years of running a small-state, safe-seat campaign, maybe it’s something else. But, he is unlikely to get the nomination and if he does, he is highly unlikely to beat Trump.In 1988, he staffed up with rather snooty east-coasters and then he killed his own campaign—even his decision to get out wasn’t done well. He ran a laughably poor caucus campaign in 2008. By 2008, a serious candidate had access to the resources and know-how to at least make a basic organizational effort at running here, if he or she wanted to. He didn’t seem to have the ability to do anything other than try to ride in on his name ID. In many precincts (including mine), he wasn’t viable, which means poor organization and his supporters didn’t know what to do after that happened, which means poor training. If you want to run here, at least lock down the basics.The guy is just a lousy presidential campaigner. I’m okay with being proven wrong on this, because I would love to have him be president. But, I won’t support him in the primary—particularly with so many good alternatives—and I fear for the party if he is our nominee.
CAUTIONARY NOTE
All of us are being counseled by our betters to suck it up,
stop whining, and get on board for Uncle Joe because he is our best bet,
perhaps our only bet, to beat Trump. It
is worth reading this from Josh Marshall’s TPM before we take the pledge.
Friday, April 26, 2019
JOE SUPPORTED THE CRIME BILL, BUT THAT WAS A DIFFERENT TIME
We all know that Joe Biden was a senatorial leader in
passing the 1994 federal crime bill.
This law, supported by members of the Black caucus and Bernie Sanders, by
the way, in conjunction with state laws, effectively criminalized the purchase,
sale, or use of certain drugs, resulting in millions of Black men being put in
jail for long periods of time. It was
part of the “war on drugs.” Those
targeted were Black men and women and non-college educated drug pushers. The punishment for use of crack cocaine was
much higher than for the use of other forms of cocaine, thereby effectively focusing
law enforcement efforts on inner city Black communities.
Now, there is a new drug crisis, the excessive use of
opioids. Scores of thousands of people
are dying of overdoses of drugs even more dangerous than cocaine. Non-college educated White users are dying at
so great a rate that the national life expectancy rates for White non-college
educated men have actually declined
for the first time in living memory.
This time, the excessive use of dangerous drugs is declared
not a public safety or crime crisis but a “public health emergency.” The victims are White, and the pushers are
doctors and corporate officials. No one
is suggesting putting users in jail.
Since the drugs are prescribed by doctors, it is not even clear that
their possession is a crime. Opioid
users do not lose their right to vote.
Does anyone see a pattern here?
Thursday, April 25, 2019
SAY IT AINT SO JOE
Sigh, so Joe Biden is in. His sole claim to the nomination is that only he can beat Trump. Is that true? I don't know. Maybe anybody can beat Trump. Maybe nobody can beat Trump. Maybe Bernie can and Kamala can't, or Kamala can and Bernie can't, or a ticket of Mayor Pete and Amy Klobuchar or Booker and Beto can. Maybe Biden should be every candidate's first choice for Vice President, since he has more experience at that job than anyone since Spiro T. Agnew.
I cannot tell you how depressing I find it all.
On the other hand, it is spring, and I saw a beautiful bright red cardinal this morning on my walk.
I cannot tell you how depressing I find it all.
On the other hand, it is spring, and I saw a beautiful bright red cardinal this morning on my walk.
Tuesday, April 23, 2019
IMPEACHMENT
Well, that didn’t work, so I will move on to the subject of
impeachment. In the past seventy –two hours
I have read and listened to endless discussions of the question, many from
people I respect. I am sure this is true
of all of you as well. I am going to
offer my opinion, painfully aware that it rests on predictions and factual estimates
of which I am not at all confident.
In brief, here is what I think the Democratic majority in
the House should do:
1. Launch
detailed hearings in several different committees, supported by subpoenas and,
if necessary, by legal proceedings to obtain as much precise, detailed evidence
and sworn testimony as possible. It
would be well if these proceedings extend well into the fall.
2. Meanwhile,
continue drafting, holding hearings on, and passing legislation dealing with
health insurance, drug prices, infrastructure, student loans, voter
suppression, equal rights, minimum wage, and so on, clearly acknowledging that
the Senate will not even take these bills up but presenting them as a
promissory note to the American people, to be redeemed when the Democrats take
back the Senate and the Presidency.
3. Some time in
the fall, complete its investigations and vote to censure the President, an
action I believe never before taken by either chamber.
4. Then, in
late fall, launch full scale impeachment proceedings, leading early in 2020 to
a vote to return a bill of impeachment against the president. Speaker Pelosi should deliver a speech on the
occasion of the vote openly acknowledging that the Senate Republicans will not
vote to remove the President from office and indeed may not even take the question
up for deliberation.
Then, the
Democrats should run on a robust platform of specific legislative proposals
based on the bills already passed in the House, and call on their base to turn
out in record numbers in order to complete the removal of Trump that the Republicans
were too craven to carry out.
All of this is based on three assumptions: first, that the
election will be decided by turnout; second, that our base is bigger than their
base; and third, that we can motivate our base sufficiently to win. I am reasonably sure of the first assumption,
quite sure of the second assumption, and not entirely confident about the third
assumption. But I think what I have
proposed gives us our best chance.
Monday, April 22, 2019
A MODEST REQUEST
I promised I would write about impeachment, and I will, but
first I would like to take a few moments to write about something that has long
puzzled me, and which I think perhaps I now understand. It is this:
Even in places like this blog, where almost everyone who comments is
pretty much left of center, if not off in the weeds with me, whenever I or
someone else says, for example, that it is a bad thing for the Russians to
attempt to muck in our elections, there are readers who immediately and reflexively
list some of the many ways in which America meddles in the internal affairs of
other nations, up to and including overthrowing a democratically elected
government and installing a friendly puppet, as in Iran.
Why do they do that?
Are they suggesting that because America does it, it is all right for
Russia to do it? Perhaps, but I don’t
think so. I don’t think they believe
that America’s doing something makes it right, as though America were the moral
exemplar for humanity. Do they think
this blog is read by true blue patriots who believe that America is a Beacon of
Freedom, a City Shining on a Hill? That
seems implausible. Do they perhaps think
that I myself have bought into the standard story that America was founded on the Idea
of Freedom and has been steadily bringing its public actions into conformity
with that idea for two hundred years? I
will do them the courtesy of assuming they know that I wrote a whole book
attacking that myth.
So why do they do it?
Here is what I think. Living in a
country whose politicians, public intellectuals, scholars, pontificators and
bloviators all accept and endlessly repeat these smug, self-congratulatory,
manifestly false myths drives some people a little crazy. It causes them such mental pain that it is as
though they were condemned to a level of Hell inhabited by demons who spend all
their time scraping their fingernails across slate blackboards. They are in a perpetual fury, and simply cannot
control themselves when they hear something that sounds as though it were yet
another knee-jerk praise of America, regardless
of who is speaking or writing.
Now, I understand what it is like to suffer from this
condition. Its symptoms first appeared
in me sixty years ago, and in one early attack of the fever, triggered by an
agitated, fruitless argument about nuclear weapons with a young Zbigniev
Bzrezinski, I wigged out, had an anxiety attack, and came to running as fast as
I could down Massachusetts Avenue toward Harvard Square sweating
profusely. Several Valium and a retreat
into the higher reaches of pure theory were required to reclaim my equanimity. One of the indirect consequences of that
attack was In Defense of Anarchism.
So I am going to ask a favor. Would those of you afflicted with this
entirely understandable disorder just assume that in this space, all of that
may be taken as given?
Thank you.
CORRECTION
An old friend vastly more knowledgeable in the law than I writes to correct me on one crucial point. Mueller did not say that he found no evidence of a conspiracy. He said that he found insufficient evidence to conclude that there had been a conspiracy, a very different thing. I stand corrected.
Sunday, April 21, 2019
THE MUELLER REPORT
I have now read the Mueller Report, all but one Appendix
[see below]. You can find it here. Since I suspect very few of you will plow
through it, I will spend this post giving you my take on it.
The Report is 458 pages long, and as one would expect in a
document produced by lawyers, it is awash in footnotes, more than two thousand
of them. It is divided into two Parts
followed by four appendices. Part I
considers Conspiracy, Part II considers Obstruction of Justice. Two appendices list acronyms and people
mentioned. A third gives Mueller’s written questions to Trump and Trump’s “answers.” The fourth lists completed and on-going
prosecutions. I did not read Trump’s “answers.” I don’t think I missed much.
Part I is 200 pages long, and it tells a story with which we
are pretty much familiar. The Russians
tried to get Trump elected. The entire Trump
world welcomed the help and had endlessly many meetings and contacts with all
manner of Russians, both about the famous emails and about the Trump Tower
project. Did Trump and his coterie conspire with the Russians to corruptly
influence the outcome of the election?
Mueller concludes that they did not.
What about collusion? Recall the definition I surfaced on
Google:
Collude: cooperate in a secret or unlawful way in
order to deceive or gain an advantage over others.
Did they collude? Did
they ever! Lord knows they tried. But I have had my say about that. What interested me was Part II, on
obstruction, because here I learned something.
Not about the facts, by and large.
They are pretty well already known, thanks to some superb investigated
journalism and a monumentally leaky White House. No, I learned something about the law, which
I will now relay to you. I ask pardon of
the lawyers among you, to whom this will be old news.
Obstruction of Justice
is a crime with three elements. These
are The Obstructive Act, the Nexus to an Official Proceeding, and Intent.
The obstructive act is the thing the person is accused of
having done.
The nexus to an official proceeding is the connection to
some legal or other official proceeding – a trial, a grand jury process, a
Congressional hearing or investigation – that is obstructed or interfered with
by the obstructive act. The official
proceeding need not actually be under way.
It is sufficient that it is reasonable to believe that such a proceeding
– a trial, a grand jury hearing – will take place.
And the intent is the conscious and deliberate purpose of the
accused corruptly to interfere with or obstruct the proper legal
proceeding.
So, to prove, let us say, that someone is guilty of
obstruction of justice for bribing a witness to give perjured testimony in a
trial, one would need first to show beyond a reasonable doubt that the accused
had offered money or something else of value to a prospective witness to lie
under oath; then one would have to establish that an actual trial was taking place
or could reasonably be expected to take place in which the individual could reasonably
be expected to be called as a witness.
And finally one would have to show beyond a reasonable doubt that the
accused understood all of this sufficiently actually to intend by the offering
of the bribe to be soliciting false testimony.
Part II of the Mueller Report consists in the main of ten
parts, in each of which a separate act imputed to Donald Trump is then
subjected to this pattern of analysis.
For example, the eighth act is: “The
President orders McGahn to Deny that the President Ordered the Firing of the
Special Counsel.” Each part begins with
a brief Overview, followed by an extended statement of the relevant facts [with
a gazillion footnotes], and then an analysis of the Obstructive Act, the Nexus
to an official proceeding, and Intent.
In six or seven of the ten analyses [I was reading fast and
did not keep track] Mueller concludes that the evidence establishes that each
of the three elements of Obstruction is present. In the remainder, he indicates that the
evidence falls short of establishing one or another of the elements.
In a normal prosecutorial proceeding, the next step would be
for the prosecutor to seek a grand jury indictment of the accused on each of
the six or seven counts that meet the evidentiary and legal threshold. But Mueller stops dead, and does not. Why? Because
he considers himself bound by the opinion of the Office of Legal Counsel of the
Department of Justice that a sitting president cannot be indicted.
But couldn’t Mueller at least conclude by saying that Trump
would have been indicted were he not a sitting president? This is interesting. Mueller says that the usual recourse for
someone accused of a crime is to go to trial [to have his or her day in court,
as the saying has it], where the accused can cross examine witnesses, put on an
affirmative defense, make arguments to a jury, and be judged by “a jury of his
peers.” But because Trump cannot be
indicted, he does not have that opportunity, and Mueller says it would be
unfair to accuse him. So Mueller walks
right up to that line and stops.
In short, Mueller does not merely provide Congress with a “road
map for impeachment,” as many commentators have said. He takes Congress by the hand and leads it
right up to the finish line of that journey, and then says, “The next step is
up to you.” If I may on Easter Sunday
invoke an Old Testament image, Mueller leads the Democrats to the mountain top,
shows them the Promised Land, but says he himself shall not go with them.
Saturday, April 20, 2019
INTERIM REMARK
OK, I have read Volume I [200 pages ugh]. Did the Trump campaign collude with the Russians?
Remember: Collude: to cooperate in a secret or unlawful way in order to deceive or gain an advantage over others.
See pages 185-188 of Volume I of the report, which makes it clear that the Trump campaign tried to collude, and also makes it clear why Mueller et al. chose not to prosecute under available statutes.
[spoiler alert: Don Jr. was too dumb to know that what he was doing was illegal.]
Remember: Collude: to cooperate in a secret or unlawful way in order to deceive or gain an advantage over others.
See pages 185-188 of Volume I of the report, which makes it clear that the Trump campaign tried to collude, and also makes it clear why Mueller et al. chose not to prosecute under available statutes.
[spoiler alert: Don Jr. was too dumb to know that what he was doing was illegal.]
I AM A SLOW READER
It is 9:54 a.m. and I am 150 pages into the Mueller report. My goal is to finish it on Easter Sunday.
Friday, April 19, 2019
GOOD FRIDAY
I want to say something about the Mueller report, but I
first I need to make at least a brief response to the many interesting comments
sparked by my recent posts.
First things first. I
am appalled, chagrined, and embarrassed to admit that I wrongly attributed the
invention of Linear Programming to Wassily Leontief instead of to Leonid
Kantorovich. Leontief invented
input-output analysis. Mea culpa, mea culpa, mea maxima culpa. Or, as they say in the neighborhood I came
from, SCHMUCK!
Second, I hope it is obvious by now that regardless of my
feelings about Mayor Pete, if the wins the nomination, I will work as hard for
him as I did for Clinton, whom I hate. I
can be rightly accused of many things [including ignorance – see above] but not
of self-defeating political purity.
Finally, from the comments, including a fascinating screed
passed on to me by Professor David Auerbach, it is obvious that I don’t know
beans about Accounting. The example I
gave in my essay was what we philosophers call a thought experiment, or as it
is now referred to, a trolley car.
However, the knowledgeable critiques of my cardboard example simply
confirm my central point, which is that the sort of market based determination
of economic decisions which von Mises argued would always be superior to
socialist planning are now impossible, and have long been replaced by decision
making that has an unavoidable quasi-political structure. There is much more to be said, but I want to
talk about Mueller.
Some commentators on this blog have pooh-poohed the charges
of collusion, insisting that there is
no evidence of that, even though, to many of us, the evidence has been in plain
sight. Now that the Mueller report is
available, even with redactions, I think the facts are clear.
Let me begin with the word “collusion.” By now we all understand that there is no statute
concerning collusion. There are statutes
concerning conspiracy, including, but not limited to, the Racketeer Influenced
and Corrupt Organizations, or RICO statute.
Mueller concluded that he did not have admissible evidence sufficient to
make a case beyond a reasonable doubt of violations of RICO and other
applicable statutes.
Bummer.
However, that does not even address the question whether
there was collusion between the Trump campaign and the Russians. That is not a legal question [there being no
statute criminalizing collusion]. That
is a question of fact and ordinary English usage.
So, what is collusion?
Or rather, what does the word “collusion” mean in ordinary English? Well, I asked Google, and this is what it
told me:
“Collude: cooperate
in a secret or unlawful way in order to deceive or gain an advantage over
others.” [By the way, nice note: the word comes from the Latin meaning “to
play together.”]
Did Trump and his campaign cooperate in a secret or unlawful
way in order to deceive or gain an advantage over others? Did they ever! Mueller’s report is replete with countless
examples of exactly that. I won’t go
through them all. You can do that
yourselves. With whom were they
cooperating? With the Russians, with one
another, endlessly, clumsily, eagerly, enthusiastically, sometimes successfully
and other times not. Did they
collude? From the detailed evidence of
the Mueller report, they seem to have done very little else!
Did it do any good?
Who the hell knows? It is hard enough
to tell whether TV advertising helps a campaign, whether personal appearances
help, whether free media help, whether having a deep baritone voice helps. But did they collude? Did they give it the good old college try?
You bet!
Wednesday, April 17, 2019
1054, 1517, AND ALL THAT
Something big is happening in the Roman Catholic
Church. I speak as an outsider, a
non-believer, but also as an interested observer of the oldest continuous
functioning bureaucracy in the Western world.
The Church has undergone two great and apparently permanent schisms
[along with many smaller ones]: The
schism of 1054, which separated the Roman Catholic Church, headquartered in
Rome, from what became the Eastern Orthodox Church, originally with its
headquarters in Constantinople; and The Reformation, which splintered the
Church and produced Calvinists, Lutherans, Methodists, Pietists, Baptists, Anglicans,
Episcopalians, and even Quakers and Shakers.
It is worth recalling that what we call The Reformation and date to 1517
was actually a three centuries long evolution, the eventual unfolding of which
could not have been anticipated by John Calvin, Martin Luther, Jan Hus, Henry
VIII, or any of the other significant players in that great drama.
The crisis now engulfing the Catholic Church has, it seems
to me, three roots or causes, which are complicatedly intertwined. The first is of course the deep systemic
corruption throughout the Church evidenced by the sexual scandals, which are so
widespread and so completely implicate virtually the entire Church hierarchy
that no palliative remedies can possibly succeed. The second, associated with the first, is the
ever-greater difficulty of recruiting enough young men to staff the clergy and
replace those dying out or retiring. The
third is the attempt to bring the Church into the modern day by such reforms as
celebrating the Eucharist in the vernacular, which, while to some degree
successful, have triggered a powerful conservative backlash that reaches all
the way to the Vatican.
As always, money, tradition, and entrenched interest operate
against any fundamental change, but that was, if anything, more true half a millennium
ago when the Protestant Reformation erupted, took hold, and split the Christian
world.
I do not have a dog in this hunt, as they say down here in
the Southland, so I am simply a fascinated observer. I rather doubt many of us will live long
enough to see this play out to the end.
WHY I WON'T BE VOTING FOR MAYOR PETE
One of the things I have learned in my long, mostly
uneventful life is that people are not stupid.
They may be uneducated, they may be ignorant, they may be parochial, and
of course they very well may be prejudiced in one or many ways, but they are not
stupid. People can size one another up
pretty accurately, even at a considerable distance, about the things that
matter to them.
I first was made aware of this elementary fact relatively
late in life when, in the seventies, I had a shot at a variety of academic
administrative positions. Despite what I
thought of as a pretty impressive resumé, I never got past first base. The reason finally dawned on me. The folks evaluating my credentials said
publicly that they were looking for a candidate with experience, educational
imagination, flair, and a strong vita,
but whether they were honest to themselves about it or not, what they wanted to
know at base was the answer to one question:
If the students occupy the Administration building, will you be with
them or with us? The question was never
asked, of course, but every selection committee could smell at fifty paces that
I could not be could not be counted on to say “I’ll be with you,” and that would
end the interview.
I thought about this after reading that long take down of Mayor
Pete Buttigieg in Current Affairs by
Nathan Robinson. Here is one passage in
Buttigieg’s autobiography, quoted by Robinson, that caught my eye:
“In April 2001, a student group called the Progressive
Student Labor Movement took over the offices of the university’s president,
demanding a living wage for Harvard janitors and food workers. That spring, a
daily diversion on the way to class was to see which national figure—Cornel
West or Ted Kennedy one day, John Kerry or Robert Reich another—had turned up
in the Yard to encourage the protesters.
Striding past the protesters and the politicians addressing
them, on my way to a “Pizza and Politics” session with a journalist like Matt
Bai or a governor like Howard Dean,
I did not guess that the students poised to have the greatest near-term impact
were not the social justice warriors at the protests […] but a few mostly
apolitical geeks who were quietly at work in Kirkland House [Zuckerberg et al.]”
“… [T]o this day,” Robinson observes, “it hasn’t even
entered his mind that he could have joined the PSLM in the fight for a
living wage. Activists are an alien species, one he “strides past” to go to
“Pizza & Politics” sessions with governors and New York Times journalists.
He didn’t consider, and still hasn’t considered, the moral quandary that should
come with being a student at an elite school that doesn’t pay its janitors a
living wage.”
As it happens, I was in Harvard Yard on April 21, 2001, the
day the protest began. I had been asked
by a young Philosophy Assistant Professor Susanna Siegel [now Edgar Pierce
Professor of Philosophy] to meet with her class, which had just read In Defense of Anarchism. When I showed up at the class, Susanna told me
that a group of undergraduates were planning to occupy Massachusetts Hall as
part of the Living Wage Movement. I went
along to their meeting in the basement of Matthews Hall [where, fifty years
earlier, I had lived as a Freshman], and when they grabbed their cellphones,
laptops, and water bottles and ran off through the Yard to Massachusetts Hall,
I trotted along after them with my briefcase and umbrella [there was a threat
of rain.] We all sat on the floor and
sang songs while some Harvard bureaucrats bustled about fussily. The students stayed for days, as Buttigieg
indicates, but I remained only for a few hours, before going back to Susie and
UMass. When I left, I congratulated
them, warned them that my experience suggested Harvard would never give in [it
did not], and told them they were fighting the good fight.
That Mayor Pete was not with us that day is entirely forgivable. That it would never have entered his mind to
join us is not.
Tuesday, April 16, 2019
SO WHY AREN'T WE HAVING FUN?
Herewith the last portion of the paper I have been serializing, for your amusement.
It would seem, if this
argument is correct, that things are proceeding just as Marx anticipated. As capitalist social relations mature, the
elements of socialist planning begin to develop deep within the corporation,
which is truly the womb of capitalism.
Why then are the prospects for social and economic justice so bleak? Why has the term “late capitalism,” once used
by socialist theorists to describe what they confidently believed to be the
death throes of the established order, now become a wry joke shared, with sighs
and the rolling of eyes, by aging radicals like myself? Why have any signs of a true movement of the
masses died out, to be replaced by an identity politics that is fundamentally
assimilationist rather than revolutionary in its thrust? In short, if all is going as predicted, why
aren’t we having any fun?
The answer, I think, is that along with everything that
he got right, Marx got three big things wrong, with the result that the
liberatory potential he saw in the internal contradictions of capitalism is
nowhere in evidence today. Let me say
something about each of these failures of analysis or prediction.
First, Marx completely failed to anticipate that the
capitalist state would develop the ability to manage and, to some extent, to
control the increasingly wild booms and busts that threatened to destroy the
capitalist order. He quite presciently
foresaw that the ever more rational organization of production within the firm
would come into contradiction with the anarchic distribution of the market,
resulting in crises of over-production and under-consumption. The great crash of ’29 was just what the good
Doctor of Philosophy ordered, albeit too late to gladden his heart.
But Marx was convinced that capitalists, confronted with
disaster, would be unable to coordinate their actions in order to save their
skins. In an odd way, he was too much in
thrall to the classical economic theory he had subjected to such a penetrating
critique in Capital. It took imaginative theoretical and practical
defenders of capitalism like Keynes and Roosevelt to see that with far-sighted
fiscal and monetary policies, the state could sufficiently dampen the business
cycle to enable capitalism to survive.
To put the point differently, Marx, very much in common with the other
economists of his day, failed to see how powerful the state had become under
capitalism.
The pulse still quickens in the circles I frequent when
the tech stock market bubble bursts or Paul Krugman forecasts a calamitous reversal
in housing prices, the way old war horses flare their nostrils and stamp their
hooves at the sound of distant trumpets.
But the truth is that our corporate masters will never again allow a
serious threat to the foundations of the economic house they have built.
Our mature capitalist economy is no longer the unplanned,
unintended consequence of the playing out of market forces, for all the lip
service that its apologists pay to “free enterprise” on festive occasions. Rational planning is as pervasive at the
macro-economic level as it is within the firm.
But that planning – far more sophisticated and nuanced than either Marx
or the state planners of the Soviet Union
could have anticipated – is securely within the service of private interests,
not the public good.
The second obstacle to the development of a revolutionary
working class movement has been the persistence of pre-capitalist passions and
attachments that Marx was convinced capitalism’s invasive rationalization of
economic life would weaken and ultimately destroy – nationalist loyalties,
ethnic identifications, racial antagonisms, and religious faiths. The secularization of life seemed to be well
under way in Marx’s time. The Catholic
Church had lost its grip on public life in France , Germany , and Italy . The ancient antagonism of the urban and the
rural was dissolving, as Marx had indeed predicted. And the ever-increasing mobility of both
labor and capital bid fair to consign nationalist sentiment to public holidays
and political speeches.
The optimistic confidence that class interests would
defeat the irrationality of nationalism reached its height in 1914, as
socialists world-wide – my grandfather among them – refused to believe that
French and German workers would fight one another in the trenches at the behest
of their capitalist masters. With the
bloody refutation of that belief, something died in the heart of the socialist
movement. To be sure, the unanticipated
success of the Bolsheviks in Russia encouraged some to believe that despite
all, the proletarian movement was on the march [though not my grandfather, who
sided with Norman Thomas and the Mensheviks].
But the success first of the Soviet Union and then of Mao’s revolution
in China, important as they were to the unfolding of the twentieth century, had
nothing at all to do with the birth of socialism in the womb of capitalism.
In the United
States , race had already opened a chasm in
the worker’s movement that, in a revised form, persists to this day. When four million Black men and women walked
out of slavery, prepared for the free labor market with agricultural, craft,
and industrial skills that they had used as slaves to make the South rich, they
encountered implacable hostility from white workers, whether immigrant or
native-born. White workers until after
the Second World War struck devil’s bargains with their employers, conceding
labor peace and low wages in return for whites-only hiring practices. This fact, perhaps more than any other,
doomed the American working class movement to eventual failure.
At this nightmare moment in recent history, little need
be said about the persistence and intensification of ethnic and religious antagonisms
throughout the world. Try as we may, we
socialists can no longer cling to the hope that class interests will unite men
and women across national, ethnic, racial, and religious divides in a vibrant
revolutionary movement to replace capitalism with a humane, just, egalitarian
social order. Capitalists are doing
their part. Not only are they crafting
the elements of rational planning that a socialist economy would require. They are in the forefront of efforts to put
the divisiveness of race, ethnicity, nationality, and religion behind us, for
these divisions are not good for business.
It is the people who remain mired in self-destructive and self-defeating
irrationality.
Marx’s third and most serious mistake concerns the
direction in which the labor force evolved as feudalism gave way to early
capitalism, and then to the mature capitalism we see today. In the middle of the nineteenth century, when
Marx was doing the British Museum research on which his hauptwerk was based, one of the most striking changes taking place
in British society was the destruction of the old crafts – weaving, spinning,
woodworking, and the rest – and the incorporation into machinery of the skills
they once required. In late feudal and
early modern times, a working man was known by the trade he plied, learned in a
long apprenticeship and symbolized by the kitbag of tools he brought with him
to the job. The complex social structure
of crafts left indelible marks on the family names that so many Americans bear
today – Wheelwright, Carver, Chandler ,
Taylor, Cartwright, Schneider, Schreiber, Weaver, Shepherd, Farmer, Smith.
Capitalism ate away corrosively at the craft tradition,
deskilling artisans and turning them into a homogeneous pool of semi-skilled
workers who could master the skills of a factory job in a few weeks and were
thus available to be moved easily from job to job by the fluctuations in the
market demand for industrial labor. Marx
saw this progressive homogenization of the labor force as the correlate to the
process by which small independent entrepreneurs were being crushed by
competitive forces and absorbed into larger and larger firms driven to expand
by a need to achieve control over their input and output prices. He foresaw a world in which a united
industrial working class would confront concentrated capital, until finally,
when a major crash had fatally weakened capital, labor would seize control of
the means of production and substitute socialist planning for capitalist
anarchy.
It was not only an inspiring dream, at least for some of
us. It was also a quite plausible
projection of trends that were working themselves out powerfully in Marx’s
day. But it was not to be. On the side of capital, as Marx anticipated,
relentless concentration did take place, leading to the world of vast
multi-national conglomerates with which we are all familiar. To be sure, a subordinate domain of small
business flourished, rather like the flora that live under the soaring canopy
in an Amazon rain forest. Nevertheless,
Marx got that part of the future right.
It is on the side of labor that things have not
progressed as Marx imagined they would.
For a time, the growth of industrial capitalism did indeed produce a
vibrant labor movement that evolved very much as Marx expected. First individual factories, then entire
industries, finally entire national labor forces were organized, giving rise in
the United States
to the American Federation of Labor and the Congress of Industrial
Organizations, while in Europe the labor
movement was so successful that it was able to create and sustain major
political parties.
But as industrial
capitalism gave way to a complex mix of industrial and service firms with huge,
bureaucratically managed assemblages of employees, the leveling and
homogenization ceased. There came into
existence a pyramidal hierarchy of job categories with sharply unequal wage,
salary, and compensation schedules. Instead
of a world in which the propertyless masses sell their labor and are poor,
while the owners of capital hire labor and live on the profits from this
unequal exchange, we see today an economy in which even the very rich, by and
large, are salaried, and capital is owned by share holders who exercise little
or no control over what is nominally their property. Indeed, comfortably compensated and securely
tenured economists like Paul Samuelson, bemused by the reversibility of their
equations, have taken to saying that it makes little effective difference to
the economy whether capital hires labor or labor hires capital.
This highly unequal allocation of the rewards and burdens
of labor has undermined that solidarity on which Marx was counting. Steel workers, miners, and textile operatives
could forge some degree of unity, despite their geographic dispersion and the
many differences in the nature of their jobs.
Even hospital and hotel workers, secretaries and fast food workers,
could find some common ground on which to stand in their struggle against the
exploitation inflicted on them by capital.
But whatever theoretical connections there might be between them and
lawyers, middle managers, and tenured college professors, the gap in the
salaries and conditions of labor between the two groups, the utter disparity in
their life experiences and life chances, have made a fruitful solidarity out of
the question. Workers have grown
progressively less unified, until at long last, Organized Labor has come to be,
and to be seen, as nothing more than an interest group, on a par with, but
often less powerful than, gun owners, retirees, and fundamentalist Christians.
All of us are familiar with this world, for it is, after
all, our world, and we understand intuitively that our life chances are
determined not by whether we own the means of production, but rather by where
on the pyramid of jobs we end up. It is
worth taking a moment to look at a few facts and figures, simply to remind
ourselves just how steep that pyramid is.
I am referring not to the much-discussed explosion of compensation at
the highest executive levels, but to the deeply entrenched inequality all up
and down the pyramid. [These numbers
come from Bureau of Labor Department tables, and date from 2004, the latest
year for which the statistics are available on their website.]
In the town of Amherst ,
Massachusetts ,
where my university is located, a teacher at the Amherst Regional
High School with a
Master’s Degree will, after fourteen years, earn $61,353 a year. If her husband is a fireman in town who is
also trained as an EMT, his salary will go up to $45,000 a year. Their combined family income will then be larger
than that of ninety percent of the families in the United States . Stop and think about that for a moment: a high school teacher and a fireman. If the teacher had married a professor at the
University, by the time he had risen to the rank of full professor and served
in that rank for a while, he might well be earning about $140,000 a year. Their family income would then be larger than
that of roughly 97% of all American families.
By any reasonable classification, they should count as among the rich,
and yet all of us are so conditioned by the meretricious images of the mass
media that we would unthinkingly describe them as a “middle-income family.”
Not surprisingly, the numbers are much worse for
African-American families. Now that the
federally mandated minimum wage is on its way up to $7.25 an hour, a Black
husband and wife working fulltime minimum wage jobs can look forward to the
time when their annual household income of $29,000 puts them solidly in the
Black Middle Class, with more than forty percent of Black households doing less
well.
The shape of the income pyramid in America has
changed very little in the past century and more, save to become somewhat
steeper. This in itself is odd, when we
reflect that over that period of time America has been transformed from
primarily an agricultural economy into to an industrial economy, then to a
service economy, and now to an information age economy. One might plausibly have expected that so
radical a series of transformations would work some alteration in the pattern of compensation, but it has not.
Apologists for capitalism, who are now as common as houseflies,
like to offer two connected explanations for the inequality in wages and
salaries, which taken together are intended as a justification as well. The first rests on a misinterpretation of a
famous eighteenth century mathematical theorem, the second on a common logical
fallacy.
Mathematics first.
Leonhard Euler, the great Swiss mathematician, proved a
theorem about linear homogeneous functions that was, in the nineteenth century,
given an important economic interpretation.
The theorem was construed as saying
that under certain conditions, the wages paid to workers in a free and
competitive labor market exactly equal their marginal contribution to the
output of the firm for which they work, or, as it is sometimes called, their
marginal product. Thus, if a
vice-president in an executive suite makes more than a secretary in the steno
pool, that is because the vice-president contributes exactly that much more to
the productive activity of the firm. It
would be both unjust and inefficient to take away some of the executive’s pay
and give it to the secretary, even though they are both, no doubt, nice people
and hard workers.
The problem with this rationale for unequal pay is that
it turns out, upon closer inspection, not to apply to any known or even
possible capitalist system. In the first
place, the theorem holds only for economies whose production function is linear
homogeneous [assuming that it even makes sense to speak of the production function of an entire economy], and as is easy
enough to show, this is equivalent to saying that the economy is in long run
equilibrium. But as Marx pointed out,
and as every economist since has reaffirmed, capitalism is never in long-run equilibrium.
A capitalist economy is always engaged in what Joseph Schumpeter, in a
famous phrase, called creative destruction.
Furthermore, it follows directly from Euler’s equation that a firm with
a linear homogeneous production will, if it pays each of its employees his or
her marginal product, make a zero profit, and a firm regularly making zero
profit will of course cease to exist.
All of this is quite well known to all economists, but it
has not dissuaded them and their epigones from wrapping themselves in the
sanctity of mathematics whenever proposals for wage and salary equalization
surface.
So much for mathematics.
Now logic.
When economists are asked why some employees are so much
more productive than others, and hence deserving of such inflated compensation,
their standard answer is education,
or, as they sometimes say in an attempt to make the answer sound more
impressive, human capital. Actually, that last sentence inverts the real
order of explanation, and thus participates in the ideological rationalization
that I am attempting to debunk. Let me
restate the point: When asked to explain
the striking inequality in compensation schedules, economists begin by assuming
that the inequality must be justified, for to think otherwise would be to call
into question both the foundation of American society and their own comfortable
compensation. Those of us at the top of
the income pyramid must have a much greater marginal productivity, they
conclude. And how can that in turn be
accounted for? Education.
Now, it is demonstrably true that in America today,
your level of education [or, to be more precise, the number of years of
schooling you have completed – not at all the same thing] powerfully affects
where on the income pyramid you end up.
Indeed, it may be the single most significant determinant. There are very few MBA’s working on the
loading dock, and very few K through Twelvers in the executive suites.
But this fact does not imply that the shape of the income
pyramid itself is in any way determined by the levels of educational attainment
in the work force as a whole. If you
have a college degree, your chances of climbing up the pyramid at least to the
middle levels are quite good. But if
everyone gets a college degree, the pyramid will not flatten out, because there
are only so many jobs at the middle level.
To think otherwise is to commit what logicians call the
Fallacy of Composition, which is simply the mistake of thinking that because
something is true of each member of a group, it can be true of them all. Each of us, we may suppose, can with hard
work and determination, be above average, but only in Lake Woebegone can all
the children be above average.
Because the American economy is so large, it is easy to
lose sight of this simple truth. For
each individual, or for all immigrants, or for all African Americans, or even,
within limits, for all women, it is indeed true that greater educational
attainment will tend to lead to higher compensation, but that is only because
the individuals or the group will over time displace some of those in the
favored slots. If all the applicants for
jobs at a corporation present themselves to the Human Resources Office with
MBA’s, the Board of Directors will not terminate the positions of secretary,
mail room clerk, and claims adjuster and make everyone a senior manager!
There is one way in which a dramatic educational
upgrading of the entire workforce might conceivably trigger a flattening of the
entire income pyramid. With better
prepared workers available, corporations might shift to different and more
profitable production techniques, and those new techniques might result in an
array of job positions with more equal associated compensations. Economists would say that the positions
defined by the new production function had more equal marginal productivities,
which, as we have seen, is nonsense, but nevertheless, the end result might be
a flatter pyramid.
Is this likely to happen?
Well, for more than one hundred years, the average level of educational
attainment in America ,
as measured by number of years of schooling completed, has been rising. The level of education demanded by the
production techniques and job specialties in the American economy has risen
correspondingly. And the shape of the
pyramid has remained essentially unaltered.
Literacy, not to mention computer literacy, is today required even by
such poorly paid jobs as department store clerk. And yet, no flattening of the pyramid can be
discerned.
What then does explain the shape of the income
pyramid? A number of bright economists,
willing to challenge the received wisdom, have been puzzling over this question
for several generations. More than
thirty years ago, Lester Thurow, the MIT economist who served there for a while
as Dean of the Sloan
School , published a
little book called Generating Inequality
that took a fresh look at the question.
But although it is possible to give partial explanations, especially of
an historical sort, for the pattern of compensation in this or that capitalist
economy, the seeming permanence of the steep pyramid, its imperviousness to
even the most striking changes in the world economy, remains a mystery.
Thus, there is little prospect for the labor solidarity
on which a successful socialist transformation must be built. It is now the best of times and the worst of
times. Economic rationality marches
relentlessly on, while poverty and inequality harden into permanent injustice,
and racial, ethnic, national, and religious rivalries tear the world apart.
What can we anticipate for the future? What will my grandfather’s great, great
grandson, my grandson Samuel, inherit as he grows to maturity? The impetus within corporations to substitute
economic planning for subservience to market forces will strengthen, as the
managerial class responds to the imperatives of institutional rationality. Meanwhile, the obscene gap between the gilded
life chances of the fortunate and the life-threatening poverty at the bottom of
the world economy will persist and come to be seen as an inevitable concomitant
of the rational workings of the market.
There will always be class traitors like myself who rail
against the inequality from which they personally benefit. But though our excoriating tracts may bring
us tenure and advancement, the revolutionary transformation they celebrate will
seem as fanciful as the Chronicles of
Narnia.
What then is the future of socialism? If socialism is the substitution of rational
planning for the anarchy of the market, it is already upon us. If socialism is the achievement, at long
last, of justice and equality, it is a dream that has been aborted in the womb
of the old order.
THE FUTURE OF SOCIALISM PART THREE
Which brings us to the third
and most problematic of the sources of accounting ambiguity, joint production,
for that is precisely what is at stake when it comes time to allocate the cost
of the space in which the two divisions carry out their productive
activities. Speaking generally, joint
production is the use of a factor input to produce two distinct salable
outputs. In this case, the input is the
company’s building and the outputs are cardboard and boxes. An oil refinery usually generates an entire
array of products from its processing of crude, as does a slaughterhouse from
its transformation of beef on the hoof into an assortment of meat products,
hides, and other outputs. It is not too
much to say that in a modern corporation, joint production is the rule rather
than the exception.
The accountant, in preparing an annual report of a firm,
is called upon to allocate the cost of the inputs that are used jointly in the
production process. As Thomas
demonstrates, there is no neutral pattern of allocations that can determine how
much of the cost of such a factor is to be allocated or imputed to each unit of
the several outputs in whose production process it is employed. The problems are manifold, as should by now
be obvious. Thomas cites as one example
an attempt to distinguish the cost of a building in which are carried out
production processes having multiple outputs from the cost of the land on which
it is built. The problem is that tearing
down the building would so significantly alter the land values in the
neighborhood in which the factory is located that the sale price of the cleared
land would in no way reflect the cost to be allocated among the several outputs.
Well, enough is enough.
Even these remarks, which might be characterized as accounting lite, are
more than any sensible layman would want to read. Why does all this matter to someone like
myself who is trying to assess Marx’s analysis of the transition from
capitalism to socialism?
Perhaps the best
way to begin is with the classic essay by Ludwig von Mises entitled “Economic
Calculation in the Socialist
Commonwealth .” First published in the original German
version in 1920, and included in an English version in Friedrich von Hayek’s
widely read 1935 collection of essays, Collectivist
Economic Planning, von Mises’ essay is generally thought to be a
devastating dismantling of the socialist penchant for central planning. His thesis, in a nutshell, is that since the
free market does the best possible job of pricing factor inputs, through the
interplay of individual decisions to buy or sell, the very most that socialist
planners could do, in the ideal case, would be to mimic the operations of the market. Since in the real world they have no hope of
achieving that ideal, collectivist planning will always be inferior to free
market competition as a way of deciding how most efficiently to employ scarce
resources. Thus, contrary to the
expectation of Marx and his followers, socialist planning can never improve on
the unplanned outcome of the marketplace, but will fall disastrously short of
that standard, producing wastage, bottlenecks, shortages of necessary
productive inputs and calamitous failures to meet consumer demand. In the jargon of modern economists,
unfettered capitalism will tend to put an economy on its production possibility
frontier, while socialist planning will consign an economy to a position well
below and to the left of that desirable location.
The first thing
to be said is that in 1920, von Mises was dead right, and I think it is a fair
guess that Marx, had he been alive, would have agreed. Von Mises was of course looking at the
fledgling Bolshevik government that had just seized power in Russia ,
ostensibly in the name of Marx and communism.
Russia
was then still a late feudal economy with a tiny nascent capitalist sector
pretty much confined to a few cities west of the Urals. The social relations of capitalist production
had scarcely begun to grow in the womb of feudalism, and nothing remotely
resembling socialist relations of production could be discerned anywhere in Russia ’s
economy. The Bolsheviks were well aware
of this fact, and engaged in a lively – ultimately bloody – discussion about
whether it was theoretically possible to “skip a stage” and go directly from
late feudalism to socialism. Marx knew
that the answer was no, and so, I suspect, did they, but when one has
unexpectedly taken control of a vast nation at considerable personal risk, it
would have seemed unnecessarily doctrinaire to turn the state over to whatever
capitalists one could find and wait patiently for the slow evolution of new
social relationships to run its course.
Not surprisingly, what emerged in Russia , and later in the even
vaster peasant society of China ,
bore no resemblance at all to what Marx had in mind when he spoke of socialism
growing in the womb of capitalism.
So von Mises was
certainly right with regard to the world he was looking at in 1920. The market clearly did a better job of
allocating scarce capital resources than any group of planners could, even
though Russia
numbered among its intelligentsia some of the best economists in the
world. [Indeed, it is said that some
years later when the young Wassily Leontief took his brilliant new technique of
linear programming to the Soviet Commissars and offered it as a tool for
sophisticated central planning, they dismissed his offer on the bizarre grounds
that since Marx only used addition, subtraction, multiplication, and division,
Stalin had decreed that his planners must do likewise. Leontief eventually moved to Harvard, where
his theoretical innovation assisted corporate planners to manage their
capitalist empires. Many years later, he
was awarded the Nobel Prize in economics.]
But von Mises was
fundamentally wrong in his conception of the question under debate. Marx did not think that socialists could do a
better job than capitalists of running a capitalist economy. Marx had only the greatest admiration for the
explosive efficiency of capitalism. No
one has ever penned more effusive panegyrics to capitalism than Marx. What Marx said was that inevitably, ineluctably,
socialist relations of production would develop within capitalism, devised and advanced by capitalists, not by
socialist moles burrowing into the heart of enemy territory in an effort to
undermine their fortresses.
If market forces
were adequate to the task of making rational allocations of scarce resources,
there would be no internal impetus for the evolution of new ways of organizing
production. But as we have seen, in a
large modern corporation, the play of the market does not of itself resolve
questions of allocation, resource use, and profitability. Capitalists do not develop internal planning
models of economic decision making because they have been seduced away from the
faith of their fathers by tenured radicals on effete Eastern campuses who have
never met a payroll. They develop new
modes of corporate decision making because their accountants and financial
experts cannot tell them, in a neutral, objective fashion, which of the
available alternatives will be most profitable.
Our cardboard C. E. O., struggling to decide which of his division
managers has made the most significant contribution to the firm’s profits, must
somehow resolve the disagreement between the two over the proper allocation of
the fixed costs of the building in which their production takes place, and over
the proper amounts to be charged against the box division’s accounts when it
draws its raw materials from the stocks produced by the cardboard division.
Once the firm’s
president becomes persuaded by his accountant’s argument, he realizes that the
disagreements between his division managers will have to be worked out
politically – they will either have to be negotiated, or else he will have to
decide them by an exercise of sovereign authority.
In either case, what has happened, even in this very
elementary case, is that a decision originally made for the firm by the market,
and then made for the firm by an accountant, now has been transformed into a
political decision to be made essentially by some form of political
mechanism. In short, economic
calculation has been replaced by political planning.
No doubt, none of the actors in this miniature drama
would consider it in the slightest appropriate for what is usually called the
political system to get involved in deciding how fixed costs are to be
allocated in the cardboard carton firm. But though there might be many other
reasons for keeping the city, the states, or the federal government out of the
process, the principal and most plausible reason has evaporated, namely that
the decision, being economic in nature, is best made by the impartial working
of market forces. The fact of the matter is that the decision isn’t simply
economic – it is not actually an objective scientific decision at all. It is a
political decision, required in order to resolve a conflict between the
incompatible ambitions of the two division managers, one of whom is seeking to
hold his job against the threat of replacement, the other of whom is trying to
advance her career by demonstrating her ability to run a division profitably.
The situation we have analyzed in this hypothetical small
firm is reproduced throughout the modern capitalist corporate world, with
complications, elaborations, and variations that cannot even be hinted at in
our example. A major multinational corporation, as has often been remarked, is
better compared to a state than an entrepreneurial firm. Contained within it are huge bureaucratic
systems and sub-systems in whose hallways and meeting rooms men and women live
their entire working lives. The
processes by which corporate-wide calculations of profitability are made
involve considerations of tax codes, local ordinances, international trade,
exchange rates, inflation rates and regional differential development patterns
that are substantially indistinguishable from the corresponding considerations
weighed by economic planners in centralized national economies.
The running of such a corporation requires systems of
data acquisition and retrieval entirely beyond the capabilities of the
eighteenth and nineteenth century capitalist firms on whose behavior the
original models of capitalism were based. To manage such information systems,
and thereby to coordinate the decisions, the purchasing and shipping patterns,
the product development time-tables, and the promotional campaigns of the many
divisions of the firm require an extremely high level of literacy – both
linguistic and computer – on the part of lower and middle level, as well as
upper level, employees. Until it is possible
to get reliable answers quickly to questions about employee levels, warehouse
inventories, price shifts, exchange rates and capital availability, those
charged with the central planning of the corporation cannot even begin to carry
out their tasks.
Nothing resembling this level of information flow, and
consequent decision implementation, existed in the early capitalist firms, not
even in those that grew to great size in the nineteenth century. The importation into capitalist industrial
organization of the model of military command and control was due at least as
much to the sheer unavailability of any alternative way of managing and
coordinating the behavior of large numbers of people as to the ideological
affinity of the early industrial magnates for militaristic modes of
organization.
In short, when Marx talks about socialism, he has in mind
an economy whose stage of development of technology and organization is so far
advanced that national planning is technically
possible. Such a stage exhibits both a
certain level of technology of production, of data generation and retrieval,
and of communication, and also a corresponding level of knowledge and skill on
the part of workers at every level, not merely at the top. Although Marx failed to foresee the digital
computer, it is not far-fetched to say that his conception of socialism
presupposed it, or something equivalent.
Marx expected, for sound reasons, that the technology of
production, communication, and management required for the central planning and
control of an entire economy would develop first within capitalist firms, in
direct response to the pressures of competition and the demands of
profitability. And so they have. An immediate consequence of this process is
the transformation of economic calculations into political decisions, within
the firm. Thus, if by socialism we mean
the rationally coordinated planning of an entire national economy in such a way
as to transform the major economic choices of the society into political
choices, responsive to the will of the people, then it is true that socialism
has been growing within the womb of capitalism, or at least that the technical
preconditions for socialism can be seen to be developing there.
The economic systems established in the Soviet
Union , in Eastern Europe , in the
People’s Republic of China ,
and in a number of other nations self-described as “socialist,” were not in any
usable sense examples of socialism. This
description must be denied them not because of the character of their political
systems, but quite simply because they did not exhibit either the stage of
development of productive forces or the level of development of, and
rationalization of, relations of production pre-requisite for what Marx meant
by “socialism.” An economy cannot, with the best will and the strongest ruling
party in the world, move directly from a feudal or early capitalist economic
organization to socialism. The reason has nothing whatever to do with piety,
ideology, or the inexorable march of history, and has everything to do with the
impossibility of planning food production rationally when you cannot even find
out with any precision how many acres are under cultivation, or what the
pattern of crop yields is from county to county, and when your work force is
computer-illiterate.
Note, by the way, that the development of efficient
techniques of central planning within a modern capitalist corporation is
advanced, not impeded, by the ambition, acquisitiveness, and egocentricity of
the workers and managers. Switching over
to a planning system in our carton factory does not require the development of
socialist consciousness. It requires only that the objective structure of the
firm make policy-neutral calculations of profitability theoretically impossible,
as in fact they are once the second division of the firm starts to operate.
Somewhat more to the point, the coherent management of large modern firms does
not require that the capitalist mentality so often credited with the rise of
modern capitalism be somehow transcended. The same men [and recently women] who
manage the great corporations would, if they were suddenly to find themselves
running small firms in a classically competitive environment, adopt precisely
the calculations of profitability traditionally conceived as determined for
them by the free market. They do not do so when managing large corporations
simply because it is technically impossible to do so.
What, then, is the fundamental difference between
socialism and capitalism at its most advanced, rationalized, and
centralized? Under socialism, economic
decisions would be treated [I use the subjunctive because there does not yet
exist a socialist society] as collective political decisions, to be made
democratically on the basis of the aggregated will of the entire people. In a
capitalist society, decisions are taken privately, within the firm, in response
only to the interests, the will, or the pressures of those who occupy positions
of power within the firm.
The issues available for decision are not at all
comparable in the two systems. A socialist society will be presented with
choices among economy-wide investment policies or systematic wage policies that
simply do not come within anyone’s ambit of decision in a capitalist
economy. This, of course, is the
principal source of the greater rationality of a socialist economy. But the mechanisms for the acquisition and
management of information, and the consequent management of economic activity,
will have been developed and tested within the capitalist firm – within the womb of the old society.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)