Placed on this isthmus of a middle state/
A being darkly wise and rudely great
Alexander Pope, An Essay on Man
One must indeed have turned a deaf ear to the chatter of the
public square not to have heard the constant invocation of The Middle
Class. Politicians, pundits, bloggers,
even economists speak of nothing else. Presidential
hopefuls mouth the phrase more often than teenager girls say "like." But a moment's reflection will reveal that
"middle class" is a rather odd phrase indeed. In truth, a great deal of ideological insight
into contemporary America can be achieved simply by meditating on the phrase
"middle class." It is the
purpose of this blog post to initiate such a meditation.
As always, a little history is a useful propaedeutic. Old Regime France understood itself to be
composed of three Estates, each with its own system of laws and courts, its own
customs of dress, and its own sources of income. The First Estate was the Clergy, who owed a
double allegiance, to Versailles and to Rome.
The Second Estate was the Aristocracy, whose status rested on its
possession of the great inherited accumulations of agricultural land. The Third Estate was the Bourgeoisie, which
[originally] meant the craftsmen and merchants who lived in walled cities [or bourgs.]
The members of the Third Estate were in many cases a great deal
wealthier than some of the impecunious aristocrats, and the clergy, of course,
controlled vast estates which, however, belonged to the Church, so the
classification into Estates was in no way intended to be an indication of
relative wealth. The vast majority of
men and women in Old Regime France, needless to say, did not belong to any
Estate. They were, one might say,
beneath the law.
With the dramatic termination of the last vestiges of
feudalism, the system of Estates passed into history. When Adam Smith and his followers undertook
to analyze the new society emerging from feudalism, they sorted people not into
Estates but into Classes according to the position they occupied in the
economic organization and processes of the society. It was patently obvious to Adam Smith that
England was divided into three great classes:
those who owned the land, the Landed Gentry; those who owned the means of production other
than land, the Entrepreneurs or Capitalists, and those who, owning nothing save
themselves, were compelled to sell their labor for wages, the Working Class.
Understanding society in this way, Smith immediately drew
the natural and quite correct conclusion that the interests of the three
classes must be in constant and ineluctable conflict, for what went into the
pockets of the Landed Gentry came out of the pockets of the Capitalists, and what
went into the pockets of the Working Class, meager though it surely was, also
came out of the pockets of the Capitalists. Smith believed that the Landed Interest
squandered its share of the social product on the unproductive clouds of
servants with which it surrounded itself, draining wealth that would otherwise
be devoted by Entrepreneurs to the employment of productive workers. His greatest fear was what was then called
the "steady state," a situation in which so much of the wealth created
by the labor of the Entrepreneurs' employees was paid over in rents to those
who controlled the agricultural land that economic growth would grind to a
halt.
David Ricardo, writing forty-one years after Smith, had the same
vision of society as economic class warfare, and the same fear of the steady
state, but he saw even more clearly than Smith the inescapable conflict between
labor and capital. Half a century later
still, when the landed interest had declined in wealth and power, Karl Marx
made the conflict between labor and capital the centerpiece of his analysis of capitalism.
For all three of them -- Smith, Ricardo, and Marx -- the guiding
principle for the understanding of society was functional differentiation, an
understanding of the different relationship in which the separate classes of
society stood to the organization of production. Land, Labor, Capital -- those were the most
elementary analytic distinctions on which a satisfactory theory of society
could be erected.
Marx expected the lineaments of capitalist society to become
more clearly delineated as big capitals gobbled up small ones and old distinctions
within the working class were progressively dissolved by the advance of industrialization,
but by a generation and more later, when Max Weber was writing, something
different and more complicated had happened.
Class distinctions based on the relationship to the organization of production
had become intermixed with distinctions in social standing, or status, based on
education, on religion, and a host of other factors. Weber responded to this development by making
the concept of status central to his
analysis of capitalist society. The
concept of status differs fundamentally from class in incorporating a
subjective element. A person's class is determined by his or her
objective position in what Marx called the social relations of production, but
a person's status is at least in part
determined by how he or she is perceived
by others.
All of us are familiar with this fact, of course. A unionized automobile worker may actually
make more money each year than a college professor, but society will consider
the professor to have higher social standing, higher status, than the
automobile worker. At least until
several generations ago, this difference in status was marked by such
differentia as dress, body language, residential location, tastes in music and
films and art, and even by speech patterns.
Sociologists seeking to measure this distinction in social
standing or status came up with the notion of Socio-Economic Status, or SES. This transformed the complexity of the
phenomena identified by Weber into a unidimensional index, with the aid of
which sociologists could describe someone as having high, middle, or low
SES. Resurrecting the word "class"
without any of its analytical power or insight, they described society as
divided into an Upper Class of individuals having high SES, a Middle Class of
individuals having middling SES, and a Lower Class of individuals having low
SES. And so the Middle Class was born.
Two things are immediately obvious about this system of
classification. First, since it is an
expression of a continuous unidimensional index, the points of division --
between upper and middle class, or middle and lower class -- are
arbitrary. Second, no matter where you
choose to draw the lines, the sub-groups of the population thus marked off do
not at all consist of individuals who bear the same functional relationship to
the organization of the economy. Hence
the terms have only a descriptive use, no explanatory power whatsoever.
Which brings us to the current obsession with the needs,
interests, and recent hard times of the "Middle Class." A question thrusts itself upon us: Why do even supposedly progressive politicians
and commentators, who might be expected to feel some concern for the economic
hardship of working Americans, virtually never talk about "the Working
Class?" There are four reasons, I
think.
First, although the term "Working Class" has at
least some positive connotations, the term "Lower Class" [or, as it
is usually deployed, "the Lower Classes"] has none whatsoever. It is still thought to be complimentary to refer
to someone as a "working man" or "working woman," but
describing someone as "lower class" is understood to be an
insult.
Second, one of the more amusing collective fantasies, or folies à tous,
of Americans is that no one is any better here than anyone else, hence that no
one is "upper class" [save perhaps the Kardashians, who are probably
the only Americans remaining who ought
to be described as "lower class."]
Thus, politicians and commentators and economists speak as though
everyone were Middle Class -- or almost everyone, as we shall see.
Third, now that it has become perilous politically to
identify people by their racial classifications, the term "Middle
Class" has come to have the secondary meaning "not Inner City
Black." As I have observed on this
blog before, for countless millions of poor white Americans, their single most
important consolation is not their religious faith but the knowledge that they
are not Black. To repeat a phrase from my youth that I have
quoted here before, the proudest boast of many Americans, especially when
declaring their right to act as they pleased, was that they were "free,
white, and twenty-one."
Thus it is that although commentators and politicians will
frequently speak about the special needs or concerns of "people of
color," they simply never talk about the interests of the Working
Class. Indeed, even to mention the
grotesque inequalities in the distribution of wealth and income in America is
to bring accusations of "class warfare," which would have struck the
likes of Adam Smith and David Ricardo as very amusing indeed.
The fourth reason why the special concerns of the Middle
Class are on everyone's lips is that voting behavior is closely correlated with
income and wealth in America. The richer
you are, the more likely you are to vote.
Inasmuch as one third of eligible voters do not bother to vote in
presidential elections, two-thirds in off-year elections, those concerned with
affecting the outcome of elections go trolling for votes where they are likely
to find them, which is to say in the enormous "Middle Class." Even the welcome calls for an increase in the
criminally inadequate minimum wage are touted as serving the interests of the
besieged Middle Class, which is, when you think about it, bizarre.
I have noted here the apparent inability of Paul Krugman to
write or utter the words "Karl Marx."
Perhaps the phrase "the Working Class" is shunned for the same
reason -- it seems to some to be the first step down the slippery slope that
leads through "bourgeoisie" to "capitalism" and ultimately
to "Karl Marx."
It strikes me that the most radical thing I may accomplish
at the University of North Carolina is simply announcing the title of my forthcoming
course.
4 comments:
There is also, I think, often a ghost of Aristotle involved in discussions of the "middle class." The Greeks (as you, of course, know) lived with a constant and often armed struggle between property classes. Aristotle stressed the importance of a middle class as a buffer to prevent the threat of "stasis."
This notion tricked into popular political theory which is why speaking of the "vanishing middle class" is the only acceptable way to talk about inequality in America.
How the middle class can contain everyone, and vanish at the same time, is not thought about too hard.
Nor is Aristotle's solution of confiscating the wealth of people who acquire too much. . . for obvious reasons.
Very nice point, JR. I had not made that connection.
'No matter where you choose to draw the lines, the [SES-based] sub-groups of the population thus marked off do not at all consist of individuals who bear the same functional relationship to the organization of the economy. Hence the terms have only a descriptive use, no explanatory power whatsoever.'
Surely this isn't true. If people perceive themselves in terms of SES-type classifications and form their political allegiances accordingly, these classifications may well have a derivative kind of explanatory power. John acts and votes in a certain way because he believes it is in his class-interests to do so. And if his class-conception derives correctly from a SES-based classification then that classification will help to explain his behavior as a political agent.
Even though the division between Blues and Greens in the age of Justininan was pretty arbitrary this does not mean that a person's Hippodrome allegiances could not help explain either what they did or what happened to them thereafter. It certainly does not entail that these division had no impact on history. On the contrary we know that hey did.
I think you are correct. My statement was too strong. I should have said that the SES-classification does not give us the same deep insight into the structure of the society that the old class analysis does. But you are right that there are all manner of things that can be predicted from SES [such as residential location, say.]
Post a Comment