III. The Meretricious Charms of Physical Quantities
It is
tempting – particularly if one is English – to make the sign of the Wiener
Kries and exorcise these metaphysical spirits. Look to the facts, and leave the philosophy
for Germans, or academic Frenchmen!
Commodities are physical objects.
They are produced by physical processes, in which definite quantities of
physical substances are combined by the labour of real individuals in
specifiable ways. An economy is a set,
or system, of such processes – the sum total of them, in fact, no more nor
less. Performing a useful and
permissible abstraction, for the purpose of bringing within manageable control
a very wide variety of productive activities, we may represent a single
industry by means of a list, or array, or vector showing the quantities of
various physical substances that must be combined with a specified number of
hours of labour in order to produce a single unity of the physical good, the commodity,
that is the product of that industry. So
much iron, so much coal, so much rubber, so much glass, and so many hours of
labour, to produce one automobile. An
entire economy is represented by a matrix of technical coefficients. With the proper maneuvers, we may now
introduce a system of prices, a wage, and a profit rate— Or, if our tastes
incline us in that direction, we may calculate the quantities of labour, both
direct and indirect, that are required for the production of a unit of each of
the commodities produced [and consumed] in the system.
As we all
know, it is the custom to posit a system of n equations in n+2 unknowns –
namely, the n prices, the wage, and the profit rate. One of the prices is arbitrarily selected as
standard of value, and we are then able to represent a system of relative
prices in which there is one degree of freedom.
Fix either the wage or the rate of profit [or, for that matter, one of
the (n+1) relative prices] and the system is determinate. It is then a relatively simple matter to
exhibit the inverse relationship between wages and profits, to prove unsettling
theorems concerning switches from techniques with lower to techniques with
higher capital/labour ratios, and back again, and even to demonstrate, under suitable
conditions of joint production and with appropriate definitions, the
possibility of a positive rate of profit conjoined to a negative rate of
surplus value. To be sure. Very elegant, very compact, amusing perhaps,
unexpected no doubt, and requiring for exposition and explanation only the most
scientific of prose. But what is the
significance?
Steedman’s
thesis, stripped of its polemical elaborations, can be stated simply thus:
value magnitudes, defined as quantities of embodied labour, can only be derived
from the matrix of technical coefficients.
Prices, wage level, and profit level can be derived either from
values, by means of a series of transformations, or directly from
physical quantities by solution of the suitable system of simultaneous
equations. Since the values are derived
from the physical quantities, there cannot be contained in the former
any information not already contained in the latter. [The entire series of causes is contained
entirely in the immediate causes, etc etc].
Hence, value calculations are otiose; not meaningless, merely
superfluous. To be sure, we may – indeed
we must – investigate the historical, social, technological, ideological,
philosophical, and psychological causes for the states of affairs summarized in
the matrix of technical coefficients.
But no such investigation can do more than explain what is already
contained in that matrix. And no labour
theory of value, manifestly, will be of any use in accounting for the technical
coefficients.
Thus much for the preconditions of the model. Analogous conclusions can be drawn concerning
its application. From the structure of
the system of equations, it follows that the pivotal indeterminacy is the
degree of freedom relating the profit rate to the wage rate. [We shall return much later to the question
whether some one of the (n-1) relative prices might, in some manner, be determined
exogenously]. Wages and profits are
treated as a division [exhaustive in combination] of the net national product. [If one selects some appropriate socially
determined level of subsistence and incorporates it into the technical
coefficients of production, then the share of net national income going to
wages will, in some sense, be a luxury wage.
Maximum profit, π = Π, then corresponds to subsistence for the
workers.] The precise proportionality of
the division, so far as the model indicates, is determined exogenously: by
class warfare in the streets, by class struggle in the bargaining room, or on
the picket line, by democratic vote of the electorate, by dictatorial fiat,
whatever.
Put to one
side the mathematics, which is beguiling in its elegant complexity. Consider simply the procedure of selecting
one of the commodities arbitrarily as standard of value, and setting its price
equal to unity. In such a model, there
is not, in the full sense, money.
Oh, there is money of account, in a manner of speaking. If the kth commodity has been
chosen as standard of value, then everything has its k-price, the workers earn
their k-wage, the profit rate is so much of a unit of k per unit of k invested,
etc. But money as value incarnate
does not exist in the system. Indeed,
strictly speaking, so long as gold and silver enter into production processes
as physical inputs, even they cannot serve adequately as money in the
full requisite sense. [It is not clear
whether Marx himself understood this, although the Grundrissse suggests
that he did].
Capital
as such – self-expanding value, money that has been freed from all natural
encumbrances and can finally realize its true, insane [verrückt] destiny, which
is to beget more money ad infinitum – does not exist in the physical
quantities model. The “metaphysical”
objectification of exchange relationships, productive activities, and technical
relations in money is an essential fact of capitalism. It is not one of the historical,
psychological, or political background conditions of that matrix of technical
coefficients “to which, of course, much study must be devoted.” Nor is it one of a number of arrangements
that can be conjoined to the self-same matrix – as though a society were a
modular construction of prefabricated units!
Capitalism requires commodity production, and wage labour, which
presuppose money. Money [exchange
value per se] must be divorced entirely from any physical form, from any use
value, from any particular system of production. It must be available, promiscuously,
instantaneously, unencumbered by religious, historical, cultural, linguistic,
or geographical constraints. The
obsession with gold is a passing phase, a last clutching at the security
blanket of economic infancy. Only those
whose minds have not transcended their senses require, from time to time, the
sensory reassurance of clinking coins.
The true inhabitants of our brave new world can make do entirely with
credits and debits in disembodied accounts.
1 comment:
'The precise proportionality of the division (between wages and profits), so far as the model indicates, is determined exogenously: by class warfare in the streets, by class struggle in the bargaining room, or on the picket line, by democratic vote of the electorate, by dictatorial fiat, whatever.
Isn't that obviously the right thing to say?
Post a Comment